What If Middle-Class
Jobs Disappear?
Structural change is an important factor in the current rate of high unemployment. The economy is in a state of transition, in which the middle-class jobs that emerged after World War II have begun to decline.
By Arnold Kling
The most recent recession in the United States began
in December of 2007 and ended in June of 2009, according to the official
arbiter of recession dating, the National Bureau of Economic Research.
However, two years after the official end of the recession, few Americans would
say that economic troubles are behind us. The unemployment rate, in particular,
remains above 9 percent. Some labor market indicators, such as the proportion
of long-term unemployed, are worse now than for any postwar recession.
There are two widely circulated narratives to explain
what is going on. The Keynesian narrative is that there has been a major drop
in aggregate demand. According to this narrative, the slump can be largely
cured by using monetary and fiscal stimulus.
The main anti-Keynesian narrative is that businesses
are suffering from uncertainty and over-regulation. According to this
narrative, the slump can be cured by having the government commit to and follow
a more hands-off approach.
I want to suggest a third interpretation. Without
ruling out a role for aggregate demand or for the regulatory environment, I
wish to suggest that structural change is an important factor in the current
rate of high unemployment. The economy is in a state of transition, in which
the middle-class jobs that emerged after World War II have begun to decline.
As Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee put it in a
recent e-book Race Against the Machine:
The root of our
problems is not that we're in a Great Recession, or a Great Stagnation, but
rather that we are in the early throes of a Great Restructuring.
In fact, I believe that the Great Depression of the
1930s can also be interpreted in part as an economic transition. The impact of
the internal combustion engine and the small electric motor on farming and
manufacturing reduced the value of uneducated laborers. Instead, by the 1950s,
a middle class of largely clerical workers was the most significant part of the
labor force.
The Great Transition from 1930 to 1950
Between 1930 and 1950, the United States economy
underwent a Great Transition. Demand fell for human effort such as lifting,
squeezing, and hammering. Demand increased for workers who could read and
follow directions. The evolutionary process eventually changed us from a nation
of laborers to a nation of clerks.
The proportion of employment classified as “clerical
and kindred workers” grew from 5.2 percent in 1910 to a peak of 19.3 percent in
1980. (However, by 2000 this proportion had edged down to 17.4 percent.)1 Overall,
workers classified as clerical, professional workers, technical workers,
managers, officials, and proprietors exceeded 50 percent of the labor force by
2000.
Corresponding declines took place in the manual
occupations. Workers classified as laborers, other than farm or mine, peaked at
11.4 percent of the labor force in 1920 but were barely 6 percent by 1950 and
less than 4 percent by 2000. Farmers and farm laborers fell from 33 percent of
the labor force in 1910 to less than 15 percent by 1950 and only 1.2 percent in
2000.
The advent of the tractor and improvements in the
factory rapidly reduced the demand for uneducated workers. By the 1930s, a
marginal farm hand could not produce enough to justify his employment.
Sharecropping, never much better than a subsistence occupation, was no longer
viable. Meanwhile, machines were replacing manufacturing occupations like cigar
rolling and glass blowing for light bulbs.2
World War II also demonstrated the increase in the
relative importance of white-collar workers and machines. With all due respect
to GI Joe and Rosie the Riveter, it could be that Cynthia the Clerk is a more
appropriate symbol of the war effort, as logistics and communications came to
be dominant factors. Although Winston Churchill famously praised “the few” who
flew airplanes during the Battle of Britain, historians emphasize the role
played by the communications and control systems on the ground, staffed to a
considerable extent by women, in making the British victory possible. Female
clerks also played a crucial role in the process of decoding German
messages—the famous Enigma intercepts.
The structural-transition interpretation of the
unemployment problem of the 1930s would be that the demand for uneducated
workers in the United States had fallen, but the supply remained high. The high
school graduation rate was only 8.8 percent in 1912 and still just 29 percent
in 1931. By 1950, it had reached 59 percent.3 With a new
generation of workers who had completed high school, the mismatch between
skills and jobs had been greatly reduced.
What took place after the Second World War was not the
revival of a 1920s economy, with its small farming units, urban manufacturing,
and plurality of laborers. Instead, the 1950s saw the creation of a new
suburban economy, with a plurality of white-collar workers. With an expanded
transportation and communications infrastructure, businesses needed telephone
operators, shipping clerks, and similar occupations. If you could read, follow
simple instructions, and settle into a routine, you could find a job in the
post-war economy.
The trend away from manual labor has continued. Even
within the manufacturing sector, the share of production and non-supervisory
workers in manufacturing employment went from over 85 percent just after the
Second World War to less than 70 percent in more recent years. To put this
another way, the proportion of white-collar work in manufacturing has doubled
over the past 50 years. On the factory floor itself, work has become less
physically demanding. Instead, it requires more cognitive skills and the
ability to understand and carry out well-defined procedures.
The Current Transition
As noted earlier, the proportion of clerical workers
in the economy peaked in 1980. By that date, computers and advanced
communications equipment had already begun to affect telephone operations and
banking. The rise of the personal computer and the Internet has widened the
impact of these technologies to include nearly every business and industry.
The economy today differs from that of a generation
ago. Mortgage and consumer loan underwriters have been replaced by credit
scoring. Record stores have been replaced by music downloads. Book stores are
closing, while sales of books on electronic readers have increased. Data entry
has been moved off shore. Routine customer support also has been outsourced
overseas.
These trends serve to limit the availability of
well-defined jobs. If a job can be characterized by a precise set of
instructions, then that job is a candidate to be automated or outsourced to
modestly educated workers in developing countries.
The result is what David Autor calls the polarization
of the American job market. Autor and various research collaborators have
documented a number of findings that reflect this polarization:4
•
In recent decades, wage and employment growth have both been lowest at the
middle segment of the skill distribution. Wage improvements have tended to be
concentrated at the high end, and employment gains have tended to be largest at
the low end of the skill distribution.
•
This particular symptom of polarization is also prevalent in OECD countries
other than the United States.
•
In the United States, this polarization was exacerbated by the economic
downturn. While both high- and low-skill jobs have held steady, the brunt of
the recession has been borne by mid-skill workers. For example, growth in
employment in sales was 54 percent from 1979 to 1989, 14 percent from 1989 to
1999, 4 percent from 1999 to 2007, and -7 percent from 2007 to 2009. Employment
in sales was a key component of upward economic mobility after World War II,
but technological change and globalization appear to have stalled or perhaps
reversed this engine of middle-class affluence.
•
From 1980 to 2007, real wages for male workers with only a high school degree
fell by 12 percent, real wages of male workers with only a college degree rose
by 10 percent, and real wages of males with post-graduate degrees increased by
26 percent. Female workers show a similar pattern, although wage gains were
generally higher for females over this period.
Using the latest Census Bureau data, Matthew Slaughter
found that from 2000 to 2010 the real earnings of college graduates (with no
advanced degree) fell by more in percentage terms than the earnings of high
school graduates. In fact, over this period the only education category to show
an increase in earnings was those with advanced degrees.5
For example, many people earn a living as drivers,
including trucks and taxicabs. However, the age of driver-less vehicles appears
to be moving closer.
Another example is in the field of education. In the
fall of 2011, an experiment with an online course in artificial intelligence
conducted by two Stanford professors drew tens of thousands of registrants.
This increases the student-teacher ratio by a factor of close to a thousand.
Imagine the number of teaching jobs that might be eliminated if this could be
done for calculus, economics, chemistry, and so on.
It is important to bear in mind that when we offer a
structural interpretation of unemployment, a “loss of jobs” means an increase
in productivity. Traditionally, economists have argued that productivity
increases are a good thing, even though they may cause dislocation for some
workers in the short run. In the long run, the economy does not run out of
jobs. Rather, new jobs emerge as old jobs disappear. The story we tell is that
average well-being rises, and the more that people are able to adapt, the more
widespread the improvement becomes.
Challenges Due to Rapid Change
There are two challenges. One is the sheer speed of
adjustment. In a hyper-Schumpeterian economy, the main work consists of
destroying someone else's job. Garett Jones has pointed out that the typical
worker today does not produce widgets but instead builds organizational
capital. The problem is that building organizational capital in one company
serves to depreciate the organizational capital somewhere else. Blockbuster
video adversely affected the capital of movie theaters, Netflix adversely
affected the capital of Blockbuster, and the combination of faster Internet
speeds and tablet devices may depreciate the organizational capital of Netflix.
The second challenge is the nature of the emerging
skills mismatch. People who are self-directed and cognitively capable can keep
adding to their advantages. People who lack those traits cannot simply be
exhorted into obtaining them. The new jobs that emerge may not produce a middle
class. Instead, if the trend documented by Autor for the period 1999-2007 were
to continue, most of the new jobs would be low-end service jobs, for which
competition will tend to keep wages low.
The recent trend in job polarization raises the
possibility that gains in well-being that come from productivity improvements
will accrue to an economic elite. Perhaps the middle-class affluence that
emerged during the latter part of the industrial age is not going to be a
feature of the information age. Instead, we could be headed into an era of
highly unequal economic classes. People at the bottom will have access to food,
healthcare, and electronic entertainment, but the rich will live in an
exclusive world of exotic homes and extravagant personal services. The most
popular bands in the world will play house concerts for the rich, while
everyone else can afford music downloads but no live music. In the remainder of
this essay, I want to extend further this exercise in imagination and consider
three possible scenarios.
Three future scenarios
The most optimistic scenario is the one I consider
least likely. Under this scenario, the supply of workers adapts to changes in
technology. In particular, this means a future with relatively fewer workers
whose skills are limited to following directions in well-defined jobs. Instead,
more workers will have the cognitive ability, initiative, and self-discipline
to constantly update their skills, adapt to new technology, and to participate
in the creative part of creative destruction. Under this scenario, economic
growth will be very high, and median earnings will also be high.
I do not believe that this optimistic scenario will
emerge through more spending on education or even with education reform. My
reading of the research is that variations in education techniques lead to
differences in outcomes that tend to be small and transitory.6
If the optimistic scenario does arise, I suspect it
will be the result of discoveries in biology. Perhaps pharmacology will succeed
where pedagogy fails.
Turning to more realistic scenarios, I see the
desirability of the outcome depending on the extent to which institutions serve
to ameliorate problems created by disparities in ability. At one extreme,
charities and government will develop humane, rational approaches for providing
for the needs of people who are disadvantaged in an economic environment where
rewards are concentrated among those who are disciplined, self-directed
learners with creative gifts. At the other extreme, collective institutions
will be arenas in which elites compete for resources, even when they claim to
be fighting on behalf of the disadvantaged.
I would assess our current situation as closer to the
adverse scenario. Our government is very responsive to cries for bank bailouts
or to pleas for subsidies coming from well-connected companies, large (General
Motors) and small (Solyndra). That same government is much less likely to
target assistance in a charitable fashion.
Economist Steve Allen calculated that a $447 billion
spending plan could be used to pay all 14 million unemployed workers $32,000 a
year to take low-paying or volunteer jobs.7 While there may be
no practical way to implement Allen's approach, it does illustrate the
deficiencies in existing stimulus proposals. Even according to the most optimistic
estimates, these create or save many fewer jobs per dollar spent.
My guess is that the more power is concentrated in
governmental units, the less likely it is that our collective institutions will
be geared toward achieving outcomes that are charitable and make efficient use
of resources. Trying to get large sums of tax money past the grabbing hands of
rent-seeking elites will be like trying to get a stagecoach full of gold past a
horde of armed robbers.
Government's role as an employer and as a regulator is
likely to exacerbate earnings inequality going forward. Government pay scales
and contract award policies tend to place a very high weight on formal academic
credentials. This increases the advantages of advanced degrees both directly
and indirectly. The more that government requires educational credentials, the
greater the rewards to the providers of educational credentials. Of course,
becoming a provider of educational credentials requires obtaining high
credentials oneself.
I suspect that a more decentralized set of voluntary
collective institutions would achieve better results. People are less likely to
donate to institutions that provide windfalls only to elites, so that such
organizations would lose out in a competitive environment. I believe that a
scenario in which many people have dignified jobs and enjoyable lifestyles is
more likely to emerge in an environment with decentralized voluntary charities
than one with concentrated, coercive government.
To put this another way, I think it is possible that
technocrats will be able to come up with programs that offer decent work and
reasonable incomes for workers with modest skills. However, I have more faith
in a process in which technocrats must compete for charitable donations than a
process in which they compete for government power.
No comments:
Post a Comment