by Keith
Weiner
As the title
of this essay suggests, a loan is an exchange of wealth for income. Like
everything else in a free market (imagine happier days of yore), it is a
voluntary trade. Contrary to the endemic language of victimization, both
parties regard themselves as gaining thereby, or else they would not enter into
the transaction.
In a loan, one
party is the borrower and the other is the lender. Mechanically, it is very
simple. The lender gives the borrower money and the borrower agrees to pay
interest on the outstanding balance and to repay the principle. As with
many principles in economics, one can shed light on a trade by looking back in
history to a time before the trade existed and considering how the trade
developed.
It is part of
the nature of being a human that one is born unable to work, living on the
surplus produced by one’s parents. One grows up and then one can work for a
time. And then one becomes old and infirm, living but not able to work. If one
wishes not to starve to death
in old age, one can have lots of children and hope that they will care for their parents in their old age. Or, one can produce more than one consumes and hoard the difference.
in old age, one can have lots of children and hope that they will care for their parents in their old age. Or, one can produce more than one consumes and hoard the difference.
One discovers
that certain goods are better for hoarding than others. Beyond a little food
for the next winter season, one cannot hoard very much. One of the uses of the
monetary commodityis to carry value over time. So one uses a part of one’s
weekly income to buy, for example, silver. And over the years, one accumulates
a pile of silver. Then, when one is no longer able to work, one can sell the
silver a little at a time to buy food, clothing, fuel, etc.
Like direct
barter trade, this is inefficient. And there is the risk of outliving one’s
hoard. So at some point, a long time ago, they discovered lending. Lending
makes possible the concept of saving, as distinct from hoarding. It is as
significant a change as when people discovered money and solved the problem of
“coincidence of wants”. This is for the same reason: direct exchange is
replaced by indirect exchange and thereby made much more efficient.
With this new
innovation, one can lend one’s silver hoard in old age and get an income from
the interest payments. One can budget to live on the interest, with no risk of
running out of money. That is, one can exchange one’s wealth for income.
If there is a
lender, there must also be a borrower or there is no trade. Who is the
borrower? He is typically someone young, who has an income and an opportunity
to grow his income. But the opportunity—for example, to build his own
shop—requires capital that he does not have and does not want to spend half his
working years accumulating. The trade is therefore mutually beneficial. Neither
is “exploiting” the other, and neither is a victim. Both gain from the
deal, or else they would not agree to it. The lender needs the income and the
borrower needs the wealth. They agree on an interest rate, a term, and an
amortization schedule and the deal is consummated.
I want to
emphasize that we are still contemplating the world long before the advent of
the bank. There is still the problem of “coincidence of wants” with regard to
lending; the old man with the hoard must somehow come across the young man with
the income and the opportunity. The young man must have a need for an amount
equal to what the old man wants to lend (or an amount much smaller so that the
old man can lend the remainder to another young man). The old man cannot
diversify easily, and therefore his credit risk is unduly concentrated in the
one young man’s business. And bid-ask spreads on interest rates are very wide,
and thus whichever party needs the other more urgently (typically the borrower)
is at a large disadvantage.
Of course the
very next innovation that they discovered is that one need not hoard silver
one’s whole career and offer to lend it only when one retires. One can lend
even while one is working to earn interest and let it compound.This innovation
lead to the creation of banks.
But before we
get to the bank, I want to drill a little more deeply into the structure of
money and credit that develops.
Before the
loan, we had only money (i.e. specie). After the loan, we have a more complex
structure. The lender has a paper asset; he is the creditor of the young man
and his business who must pay him specie in the future. But the lender
does not have the money any more. The borrower has the money, but only
temporarily. He will typically spend the money. In our example, he will hire
the various laborers to clear a plot of land, build a building and he will buy
tools and inventory.
What will
those laborers and vendors do with the money? Likely they will keep some of it,
spend some of it… and lend some of it. That’s right. The proceeds that come
from what began as a loan from someone’s hoard have been disbursed into the
economy and eventually land in the hands of someone who lends them again! The
“same” money is being lent again!
And what will
the next borrower do with it? Spend it. And what will those who earn it do?
Spend some, keep some, and lend some. Again.
There is an
expansion of credit! There is no particular limit to how far it can expand. In
fact, it will develop iteratively into the same topology (mathematical
structure) as one observes with fractional reserve banking under a proper,
unadulterated gold standard!
Without banks,
there are two concepts that are not applicable yet. First is “reserve ratio”.
Each person is free to lend up to 100% of his money if he wishes, though most
people would not do that in most circumstances.
And second is
duration mismatch. Since each lender is lending his own money, by definition
and by nature he is lending it for precisely as long as he means to. And if he
makes a mistake, only he will bear the consequences. If one lends for 10 years
duration, and a year later one realizes that one needs the money, one must go
to the market to try to find someone who will buy the loan. And then discover
the other side of that large bid-ask spread, as one may take a loss doing this.
Now, let’s
fast forward to the advent of the investment bank. Like everyone else in the
free market, the bank must do something to add value or else it will not find
willing trading partners. What does the bank do?
As I hinted
above, the bank is the market maker. The market maker narrows the bid-ask
spread, which benefits everyone. The bank does this by standardizing loans into
bonds, and the bank stands ready to buy or sell such bonds. The bank also
aggregates bonds across multiple lenders and across multiple borrowers. This
solves the problem of excessive credit risk concentration, coincidence of wants
(i.e. size matching), and saves both lenders and borrowers enormous amounts of
time. And of course if either needs to get out of a deal when circumstances
change, the bank makes a liquid market.
The bank must
be careful to protect its own solvency in case of credit risk greater than it
assumed. This is the reason for keeping some of its capital in reserve! If the
bank lent 100% of its funds, then it would be bankrupt if any loan ever
defaulted.
What the bank must
not do, what it has no right to do, is lend its
depositors’ funds for longer than they expressly intended. If a depositor wants
to lend for 5 years, it is not the right of the bank to lend that depositor’s
money for 10! The bank has no right to declare, “well, we have a reserve ratio
greater than our estimated credit risk and therefore we are safe to borrow
short from our depositors to lend long”
Not only has
the bank no way to know what reserve ratio will be proof against a run on the
bank, but it is inevitable that a run will occur. This is because the depositors
think they will be getting their money back, but the bank is concealing the
fact that they won’t behind an opaque balance sheet and a large operation. So,
sooner or later, depositors need their money for something and the bank cannot
honor its obligations. So the bank must sell bonds in quantity. If other banks
are in the same situation, the bond market suddenly goes “no bid”.
The bank has
no legal right and no moral right to lend a demand deposit or to lend a time
deposit for one day longer than its duration. And even then, the bank has no
mathematical expectation that it can get away with it forever.
Like every
other actor in the market (and more broadly, in civilization) the bank adds
enormous value to everyone it transacts with, provided it acts honestly. If a
bank chooses to act dishonestly (or there is a central bank that centrally
plans money, credit, interest, and discount and forces all banks to play dirty)
then it can destroy value rather than creating it.
Unfortunately,
in 2012 the world is in this sorry state. It is not the nature of banks or
banking per se, it is not the nature of borrowing and lending per se, it is not
the nature of fractional reserves per se. It is duration mismatch, central
planning, counterfeit credit, buyers of last/only resort, falling interest
rates, and a lack of any extinguisher of debt that are the causes of our monetary
ills.
No comments:
Post a Comment