The Great Horse-Manure Crisis of 1894
By Stephen Davies
We commonly read or hear reports to the effect that “If trend X continues,
the result will be disaster.” The subject can be almost anything, but the
pattern of these stories is identical. These reports take a current trend and
extrapolate it into the future as the basis for their gloomy prognostications.
The conclusion is, to quote a character from a famous British sitcom, “We’re
doomed, I tell you. We’re doomed!” Unless, that is, we mend our ways according
to the author’s prescription. This almost invariably involves restrictions on
personal liberty.
These prophets of doom rely on one thing—that their audience will not check
the record of such predictions. In fact, the history of prophecy is one of
failure and oversight. Many predictions (usually of doom) have not come to
pass, while other things have happened that nobody foresaw. Even brief research
will turn up numerous examples of both, such as the many predictions in the
1930s—about a decade before the baby boom began—that the populations of most
Western countries were about to enter a terminal decline. In other cases,
people have made predictions that have turned out to be laughably overmodest,
such as the nineteenth-century editor’s much-ridiculed forecast that by 1950
every town in America would have a telephone, or Bill Gates’s remark
a few years ago that 64 kilobytes of memory is enough for anyone.
The fundamental problem with most predictions of this kind, and
particularly the gloomy ones, is that they make a critical, false assumption:
that things will go on as they are. This assumption in turn comes from
overlooking one of the basic insights of economics: that people respond to
incentives. In a system of free exchange, people receive all kinds of signals
that lead them to solve problems. The prophets of doom come to their despondent
conclusions because in their world, nobody has any kind of creativity or
independence of thought—except for themselves of course.
A classic example of this is a problem that was getting steadily worse
about a hundred years ago, so much so that it drove most observers to despair.
This was the great horse-manure crisis.
Nineteenth-century cities depended on thousands of horses for their daily
functioning. All transport, whether of goods or people, was drawn by horses.
London in 1900 had 11,000 cabs, all horse-powered. There were also several
thousand buses, each of which required 12 horses per day, a total of more than
50,000 horses. In addition, there were countless carts, drays, and wains, all
working constantly to deliver the goods needed by the rapidly growing
population of what was then the largest city in the world. Similar figures
could be produced for any great city of the time.*
The problem of course was that all these horses produced huge amounts of
manure. A horse will on average produce between 15 and 35 pounds of manure per
day. Consequently, the streets of nineteenth-century cities were covered by
horse manure. This in turn attracted huge numbers of flies, and the dried and
ground-up manure was blown everywhere. In New York in 1900, the population of
100,000 horses produced 2.5 million pounds of horse manure per day, which all
had to be swept up and disposed of. (See Edwin G. Burrows and Mike
Wallace, Gotham: A History of New York City to 1898 [New York: Oxford
University Press, 1999]).
In 1898 the first international urban-planning conference convened in New
York. It was abandoned after three days, instead of the scheduled ten, because
none of the delegates could see any solution to the growing crisis posed by
urban horses and their output.
The problem did indeed seem intractable. The larger and richer that cities
became, the more horses they needed to function. The more horses, the more
manure. Writing in the Times of London in 1894, one writer estimated
that in 50 years every street in London would be buried under nine feet of
manure. Moreover, all these horses had to be stabled, which used up ever-larger
areas of increasingly valuable land. And as the number of horses grew,
ever-more land had to be devoted to producing hay to feed them (rather than
producing food for people), and this had to be brought into cities and
distributed—by horse-drawn vehicles. It seemed that urban civilization was
doomed.
Crisis Vanished
Of course, urban civilization was not buried in manure. The great crisis
vanished when millions of horses were replaced by motor vehicles. This was
possible because of the ingenuity of inventors and entrepreneurs such as
Gottlieb Daimler and Henry Ford, and a system that gave them the freedom to put
their ideas into practice. Even more important, however, was the existence of
the price mechanism. The problems described earlier meant that the price of
horse-drawn transport rose steadily as the cost of feeding and housing horses
increased. This created strong incentives for people to find alternatives.
No doubt in the Paleolithic era there was panic about the growing
exhaustion of flint supplies. Somehow the great flint crisis, like the great
horse-manure crisis, never came to pass.
The closest modern counterpart to the late nineteenth-century panic about
horse manure is agitation about the future course of oil prices. The price of
crude oil is rising, partly due to political uncertainty, but primarily because
of rapid growth in China and India. This has led to a spate of articles
predicting that oil production will soon peak, that prices will rise, and that,
given the central part played by oil products in the modern economy, we are
facing intractable problems. We’re doomed!
What this misses is that in a competitive market economy, as any resource
becomes more costly, human ingenuity will find alternatives.
We should draw two lessons from this. First, human beings, left to their
own devices, will usually find solutions to problems, but only if they are
allowed to; that is, if they have economic institutions, such as property
rights and free exchange, that create the right incentives and give them the
freedom to respond. If these are absent or are replaced by political
mechanisms, problems will not be solved.
Second, the sheer difficulty of predicting the future, and in particular of
foreseeing the outcome of human creativity, is yet another reason for rejecting
the planning or controlling of people’s choices. Above all, we should reject
the currently fashionable “precautionary principle,” which would forbid the use
of any technology until proved absolutely harmless.
Left to themselves, our grandparents solved the great horse-manure problem.
If things had been left to the urban planners, they would almost certainly have
turned out worse.
*See Joel Tarr and Clay McShane, “The Centrality of the Horse to the
Nineteenth Century American City,” in Raymond Mohl, ed., The Making of Urban
America (New York: SR Publishers, 1997), pp. 105–30. See also Ralph Turvey,
“Work Horses in Victorian London” at www.turvey.demon.co.uk.
No comments:
Post a Comment