By Michael J. Boskin, May 1999
Adam Smith, regarded by many as the intellectual godfather of modern
economics and the case for a decentralized competitive market economy, focused
his heaviest guns on mercantilism, a topic, by the way, not without relevance
today. In the almost two and a quarter centuries since Smith wrote The
Wealth of Nations, economic systems have developed in various forms in
different places. Serious scholars as well as a much larger number of pundits
have debated their relative economic success and moral underpinnings. Within
our own profession, the center of gravity has waxed and waned among different
schools of thought and political and economic persuasions. It was not all that
long ago that Friedrich Hayek and then Milton Friedman were relatively lonely
voices calling for restraining, indeed reducing, the role of government in the
economy.
What I would like to do briefly is review a few such episodes in economic and intellectual history, to shine some light on the recent calls for abandoning the capitalist model (or, more accurately, usually some highly distorted caricature of the capitalist model) in favor of some alternative. These episodes include during the Great Depression, communism; in the post-World War II period, market socialism; as recently as the 1980s, the convergence of all economic systems to heavily managed gigantic welfare states; in the 1990s, calls for a "third way," based on some other system of values; and the almost hysterical recent calls from hedge fund managers, prime ministers, pundits and even economists who should know better to "do something" about "global capitalism." Commentaries with titles such as The Crisis in Global Capitalism, Global Capitalism RIP, Collapse of Capitalism, Who Lost Capitalism? and The Free Market's Crisis of Faith deserve a response, for their prescriptions of capital controls and even larger government almost certainly will cause great harm to those the authors claim to want to protect.
My own strongly held belief is that a limited government-based capitalist
economic system not only is the system most likely to deliver the greatest
economic progress but is the model most consistent with substantial personal
economic and political freedom. However, I want to focus primarily on results,
to play the role of positive scientist, not moral philosopher, despite the
temptation to do so given that Adam Smith himself was a professor of moral
philosophy. Let me emphasize that I am discussing large differences in the
economic role of government. Criteria for determining the appropriate role of
government are discussed below.
THE GREAT DEPRESSION
Many of us are too young to have known from personal experience but recall,
from what we were taught and what we read, that, in the Great Depression of the
1930s, a large number of intellectuals and others in Western Europe and North
America turned to communism or at least lent it a sympathetic ear, given the
horrible destitution of that period. (In the United States, real gross domestic
product fell by one-third from 1929 to 1933 and the unemployment rate reached
almost 25 percent.)
Many writers had emphasized booms and busts in economic systems or economic
history. These were not, of course, confined to the post-Industrial Revolution
capitalist market economies. In earlier times, a bad agricultural harvest could
devastate a country operating under a monarchy or feudal system. But Marx, and
others, had preached the collapse of capitalism and its tendency to exacerbate
booms and busts. Whether it is the case that an economic system that leads to
substantial economic progress is more subject to episodic downturns than those
that do not is an open question, but I know of no convincing study that
suggests this is more likely in a modern mixed capitalist economy than in other
economic systems.
But the long-run improvement in the standards of living of large segments
of the world's population has been greatest in the capitalist era, as has the
correlated evolution of personal freedom. There has never been a period in
human history that even remotely compares to the tremendous growth in material
wealth and personal freedom in the period since Smith wrote The Wealth
of Nations (see D. Landes 1998).
To be sure, large segments of mankind were left behind, both economically
and politically. As a gross historical generalization, they were in societies
that lacked both economic and political freedoms and competition. Although the
capitalist economies have wide dispersions in the distribution of consumption,
the average poor family in the United States has a standard of living well
beyond that of the average Russian family, for example, and above that of the
average American family of a couple of generations ago.(2) And the most
entrenched poverty in the American economy occurs in pockets of a
quasi-socialist economy, with little competition, private capital, or private
incentives, such as inner-city public housing and schools.
Returning to the Great Depression, the most famous economic treatise of the
time, Keynes's General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money,
was viewed by Keynes himself as an attempt to salvage capitalism itself from
the onslaught of communism. While parts of the General Theory have
subsequently been questioned, revised, reinterpreted, or rejected, what Keynes
saw himself as trying to do was much more than an intellectual exercise
explaining how an economy could wind up in a low-level equilibrium with massive
unemployment for extended periods of time, something that could not be readily
explained in the classical model because wage rates would have fallen or some
other mechanism would allow the economy to get back quickly to full employment.
Rather, he viewed himself as proposing policies by which modern capitalist
economies could mitigate some of the excesses of business cycles (although
there is nothing in the periodicity and amplitude of those fluctuations to
warrant the term <cycle>) and thereby preserve much of the basic
microeconomic structure, individual decision making, and personal freedoms of
market economies. Keynesian economics, of course, became an important part of
the intellectual justification for the growth of government in the post-World
War II era.
POSTWAR GROWTH OF GOVERNMENT
The post-World War II era has seen the expansion of the absolute and
relative size of governments in most market economies and democracies. In the
United States, for example, in the mid-1950s, during the Eisenhower
administration, federal government spending was only $70 billion; today it is
more than five times as large in constant dollars and a larger share of GDP.
Also during the Eisenhower administration, one out of every seven dollars of
the then absolutely and relatively much smaller government spending went to transfer
payments; the other six were spent on purchasing goods and services, from
defense procurement to the interstate highway system. Today the majority of the
much larger absolute and relative size of federal spending, net of interest on
the debt, is on transfer payments to people. Thus, it is not only the size but
the role of government that has changed.
Of course, in Western Europe, government had become even larger--and done
so earlier--than in the United States. By the 1970s, taxes and spending accounted
for over half of GDP, massive transfers were undertaken, and substantial
regulation, nationalization of key industries, and restrictive labor market
rules were implemented or followed. Sweden, often the darling of Western
intellectuals because of its economic performance in the early postwar period,
had at one time almost 9 percent of its GDP devoted to industrial subsidies! At
the same time, we had a communist, authoritarian, centralized, bureaucratic,
command-and-control model, most often associated with the Soviet Union and
other economies in Eastern Europe but also with important less-developed
economies such as China. Not just Hayek and Friedman thought that these
economies would collapse from the weight of all this government taxing,
spending and regulation, which would not only mean a smaller private sector but
substantial stifling of private initiative to work, save, invest, and innovate.
The other alleged "intermediate" model was the market socialism
of then Yugoslavia. A popular prediction of politicians, economists, and
pundits was that the world's economic systems would somehow converge somewhere
in the region between the Swedish and the Yugoslav economies. The capitalist
economies would grow larger welfare states, the communist countries would round
off some of their rough edges, and we would all happily converge in the
"middle." This of course was ridiculous and not just in hindsight.
Meanwhile, the United States did experience an explosive growth of
government in the 1960s and 1970s, accompanied by high and rising inflation (as
the then unindexed tax system dragged a large fraction of the population into
higher tax brackets); more regulation (both of traditionally regulated
industries and, for social purposes, often of a command-and-control structure);
and huge growth and centralization of the government. Still, the total size of
government in the U.S. economy relative to Western Europe was modest, about
two-thirds as large as measured by the government spending and tax shares of
GNP. The same could be said of Japan, the other major industrial economy.
THE CASE OF JAPAN
The rapid growth of Japan led to the next nonsensical attack on the limited-government
capitalist model. The Japanese economy grew rapidly in the postwar period up to
the 1990s, and the Japanese did many things that any economist would applaud.
They had high rates of saving and investment, worked hard and long hours. The relative
success of the Japanese economy and to a lesser extent the German economy led
in the 1980s to calls for the United States to emulate these economies. How
quaint these calls seem now, given the immense problems of the German and
Japanese economies in the 1990s. The calls were for a larger role for
government, worker/business/government councils, government direction of
private pension funds into "needed infrastructure" (a proposal both
in President Carter's 1980 reelection campaign and in Clinton's 1992 campaign),
managed trade, and an industrial policy of the government picking winners and
losers for subsidies and protection (see L. Tyson 1993; R. Reich and I.
Magaziner 1982).
Indeed, I recall in 1989 when I was first sworn into office as CEA chairman,
the first thing I did was put my personal standing and credibility on the line
with President Bush to help stop a multibillion-dollar "let's catch up
with the Japanese in analog HDTV" (high-definition TV). The fear of the
Japanese in the late 1980s was incredibly palpable. They were growing rapidly,
we were growing slowly; there was large Japanese investment in the United
States (although hardly mentioned were the larger British and Dutch foreign
investment in the United States); many predicted they would overtake or
outcompete us (see L. Thurow 1992). Some panicked pundits and political
figures, joined by some powerful business interests and some economists and
would-be economists, clamored for the government "to do something."
Clearly, the Japanese markets were not nearly as open as ours or as they should be, as a rich industrial country benefiting from the global trading system. But the notion that we should spend billions of dollars to catch up with them in a policy chosen by government bureaucrats and congressional staff seemed ridiculous to me. Knowing I would be accused of being an ivory tower academic, I called the CEOs of the firms that would likely be involved and asked to speak with their top scientific people. Every single one of them told me that we would never catch up but, even more important, that analog would soon be surpassed by digital, probably within ten years.
Of course the digital age came even sooner, and analog HDTV became
obsolete. Led by then Senator Gore and House Majority leader Gephardt, the
calls for an American industrial policy were intense. The Congress demanded the
administration list all critical technologies, presumably as a prelude to
government subsidies replacing market decisions. Fortunately, President Bush
said no to the HDTV subsidies, and we did not waste billions of dollars trying
to emulate some other economic system.(3)
Much more fundamental, whatever the merits of a particular case, was the
misreading, or perhaps misappropriation for political purposes, of Japanese
economic history. Japan's success had little or nothing to do with the
government's micromanagement of the Japanese economy. As we have seen in the
1990s, that micromanagement has caused severe problems and made it immensely
difficult to unwind foolish economic policies. In fact, the notion that the
Japanese government was heavily subsidizing "sunrise" industries
while we were foolishly ignoring them flies in the face of facts. In Japan,
heavy subsidies in terms of protection, direct subsidies, tax breaks, and the
like went to industries such as textiles, mining, and agriculture (Beason and
Weinstein 1994), which is perhaps not surprising to anybody who studies
politics because they were entrenched industries with strong political
constituencies and large employment. The same "we know better than the
market" Japanese bureaucracies tried to get the Japanese auto companies in
the 1950s to produce a version of the Volkswagen Beetle; instead they went
their own way and were highly successful. Those same bureaucracies tried to
prevent Sony from getting into the consumer electronics business. And their
fifth-generation computing project as well as the analog HDTV effort have been
colossal failures. The Japanese government tried to end the subsidies to the
electronics firms a few years ago but had to back down under intense political
pressure. Well, does anyone still believe most Americans would benefit much
from emulating the German or Japanese models?
MORE VERSUS LESS GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION
The American economy, which has been, even during our most difficult
episodes, the largest and most productive economy with the highest standard of
living among the industrial economies (Boskin 1993), appeared triumphal in the
1990s as we came out of the nationally brief, mild 1990-91 recession (although
it was regionally severe, lasting longer and reaching deeper in the Northeast
and California than in the rest of the country). The fall of the Berlin Wall
and the collapse of the communist countries, together with more access to the
then Soviet Union, demonstrated beyond doubt how pathetically poor the
communist economies were. Combined with the stagnation of Western Europe and
the collapse of the Japanese economy, events temporarily short-circuited this
attack on the greater reliance on markets and individual initiative, less
reliance on government. Governments all over the world were trying to emulate
economic systems they saw as more successful, as their citizens called out for
more personal freedom and greater economic progress.
The practical lesson on the damage done by excessive government is learned
from comparing economic performance in the United States and Western Europe
during the past three decades. Although worker compensation has been growing
more slowly for the past twenty years than in the previous two decades, the
American economy has been flexible and dynamic enough to provide employment to
virtually all those who seek it. Compare that performance with the sorry state
of Western Europe, where the unemployment rate is now 11 percent, more than
double that of the United States.
There were 30 million more working-age people in Western Europe in 1994
than in 1970. The labor force, however, grew by only 19 million, and
unemployment and government employment swelled. And there were 1 million
fewer-private sector employees in Western Europe at the beginning of 1994 than
at the beginning of 1970! What a stark indictment of an inflexible,
protectionist, highly regulated, and overtaxed economic system. By comparison,
there were about 40 million more working-age people in the United States, the
labor force grew even more, and, desspite a small increase in unemployment and
government employment, the overwhelming bulk of the workers found productive
private-sector employment. The problem of Western Europe offers us a window on
our future if we allow a marked expansion in government's role.
On the relative merits of capitalism and socialism, as we hear today calls
from economies in transition to return to central planning, let me share with
you a personal experience. I was an economics major in college some years after
Soviet premier Nikita Khrushchev shouted to an American president, "We
will bury you!" Khrushchev was not talking about military might. He was
projecting the growth of the Soviet economy relative to the slower growth of
the American economy. Khrushchev proclaimed that the Soviet economic system,
with its central planning, bureaucracy, controls, and state enterprises, was a
superior economic engine. After all, industrial production grew more rapidly in
the USSR than in the United States, and it had no unemployment and no
inflation. Of course, although prices did not rise, goods were not available on
the shelf at these unchanged prices; although everyone nominally had a job,
there was unemployment and massive underemployment; and some of that extra
steel went to produce unneeded ball bearings and hence was melted back down for
future steel production.
Little did I know as an economics undergraduate that a couple of decades
later President Bush would dispatch me to Moscow to help President Gorbachev
with Soviet economic reform. When I arrived in Moscow in 1989, in addition to
Gorbachev, who knew very little economics, I met with the head of the state
planning agency (Gosplan), the finance minister, and the head of the Central
Bank.
The head of Gosplan was supposed to preside over price reform in the Soviet
Union and thus the move to a free market. At our first meeting he inquired of
me, "Who sets the prices in your economy?" Flabbergasted, I explained
that, although we had a few industries that were regulated by the government,
for the overwhelming bulk of products the interaction of numerous producers and
still more numerous consumers determined prices in our economy. Furthermore,
repeating Adam Smith's famous dictum, I said that this invisible hand of the
market produced the greatest good for the greatest number. The head of Gosplan
repeated, "So who sets the prices in your economy?" Thinking that
there might have been something wrong with the translation, we went back and
forth several times. It was clear he could not imagine an economy in which
somebody in the government did not set the prices. He pulled out a 1960s-style
giant computer printout that listed the prices for virtually every product in
the Soviet Union. America had a market economy, I was the American president's
economic adviser, he had been told by Gorbachev that I would help, so who, he
thought, was better able to determine what the new prices should be?
I next went to the Finance Ministry in the Kremlin, where I discussed
making the ruble convertible with Finance Minister Pavlov (who subsequently
became prime minister and was involved in the coup against Gorbachev). After a
to-ing and fro-ing similar to that with the head of Gosplan, trying to explain
concepts, Pavlov motioned for me to wait in his office and disappeared through
a secret door behind his desk. Remember, this was when there was still a Soviet
Union, a Warsaw Pact, and a Communist Party. A few minutes went by, and I
started feeling a bit like a character in a Robert Ludlum novel, worrying that
no one at the embassy knew exactly where I was. Finance Minister Pavlov
eventually returned, handed me a little case, and motioned for me to open it.
Inside was a coin, the first Soviet version of the convertible ruble. On one
side was printed 1 ruble and on the other side, 1 dollar. Well, I've won
teaching awards in my day, but I knew I had a long way to go.
Needless to say, when I returned to Washington to debrief the president,
the Treasury secretary, the Federal Reserve Board chairman, the National
Security adviser, and the CIA director, I was pretty pessimistic about
Gorbachev's chances of pulling off Soviet economic reform. I told them it's
going to be a rough road; think in decades, not years. This group can't
possibly pull it off; either they'll be gone, or a political backlash will stop
the reforms.
CONVERGENCE OF ECONOMIC SYSTEMS
My personal journey is thus echoed in the intellectual and historical experiences
of the past quarter century. As mentioned above, back in the 1960s, 1970s, and
1980s--and I am told occasionally still on some college campuses--the
prevailing view was that the world's social and economic systems would somehow
converge toward a central tendency, somewhere, say, to the left of where Sweden
was in the 1970s. The communist economies, it was said, would round off the
rough edges by allowing a littler freer rein to private incentives, whereas the
advanced capitalist economies would evolve into ever larger welfare states with
more government planning, intervention, and control in their economies. We
would all happily converge roughly on the same system, with roughly the same
results.
History has performed that experiment. Compare the former East and West
Germany. Both were shattered by World War II. Both had similar problems and
opportunities. One was dosed with communism--the heavy hand of state planning,
controls and government intervention, regulation and state ownership of
virtually everything. The other, once Ludwig Erhard's reforms had created a
currency in which people had confidence and freed up prices from postwar
controls, was dosed with capitalism. The West grew into an economic
superpower--struggling now under the burden of economic integration with the
East--while the East stagnated. When the two Germanys were reunited, the
standard of living in the West was five times that in the East, which had a
spoiled environment, a decrepit capital stock, and a demoralized labor force. Indeed
the saying among East German workers was, "They pretend to pay us and we
pretend to work." That is about as close as we get to a natural experiment
in economics. And the answer is unambiguous. There is no longer any doubt about
whether there are two alternative paths to economic prosperity. Socialism and
central planning do not work. Only some form of capitalism and free markets,
despite their problems, works over the long haul.
CRITERIA FOR DETERMINING SIZE AND ROLE OF GOVERNMENT
I focus here on major differences in the role of government in the economy
and society across a broad spectrum, not disagreements over this or that
program or the relative size of the government within a modest range around
where it is now in the United States. What I believe is that the greatly
expanded role of government that some have called for would be a tragic
economic mistake. I also believe that arguments over specific programs that
might lead to a minor decrease or increase in the relative size of government
will almost certainly wind up reflecting politics. But those arguments must
also reflect the well-articulated and economically well-understood criteria for
evaluating such programs: rigorously enforced cost-benefit analyses, meaning
that the government financing of activity is potentially desirable if the
expected benefits are likely to exceed the expected costs; if the activities
cannot be undertaken by the private sector (perhaps because the benefits cannot
be appropriated by the private firms); and if our usual notions of balancing
marginal social benefits and costs to deal with externalities and public goods
apply. Decisions that affect national defense and basic research are amenable
to the applications of such rigorous criteria.
Analogous criteria have been developed for optimal tax systems, transfer
programs, and government regulation. My own reading of the evidence, to the
extent I can divorce it from my own philosophical predilections, is that we
could lower tax rates; have less and more-flexible regulation; have more market
incentives in regulation, education, and job training; slow spending growth;
reform taxes, budgets, and social insurance; and so on, resulting in a somewhat
smaller government. All these are likely to lead to a better performing economy
and, at least after temporary transitions, improve the well-being of the vast
majority of our citizens and the functioning of the programs. But that is
another story for another time. My purpose here is to talk about major
differences over the relative size of government, despite the deservedly
intense political debate about modest changes in the size and role of
government, which is important not only for ideological and economic reasons
but because development of new programs, or the relentless expansion of existing
programs, can over time lead to that sizable expansion of government with which
I am primarily concerned here.
IMPERFECT MARKETS VERSUS IMPERFECT GOVERNMENT SOLUTIONS
Markets sometimes fail. Imperfect markets, however, must be compared to
imperfect government solutions implemented by fallible people. Thus, when we
try to correct perceived externalities, we must insist on strong, sound science
and flexible market mechanisms, not on scare tactics and command and control.
When competition is stifled, naturally or otherwise, we need sensible rules,
antitrust laws, or regulation or some combination thereof enforced in a
sensible manner. We need serious protection of private property through
contract and bankruptcy law and consistent accounting standards and supervision
of financial markets in a way that maximizes openness and transparency. These
are important foundations of well-functioning, market-based economies. In my
view, the risk is that the problems we face in the American economy will lead
to too much, not to not enough, intrusion of the government in the marketplace.
The current hysteria over hedge funds is an example. The problem wasn't the
financial instruments themselves. Futures, options, and other derivatives
generate sizable net benefits when properly used in hedging various risks. Of
course, there are also potential costs in their misuse or abuse. When
ridiculous amounts of leverage provided by banks and brokerages with little or
no knowledge of the positions of the funds to whom they lend was combined with
positions that were not market neutral, potential bankruptcy loomed. This is no
different conceptually from highly leveraged borrowing short and lending long
betting on interest rate stability--the saga of the S&L industry in the United
States; nor is it very different from Asian banks or industrial companies
borrowing in dollars and lending in baht or rupiah, pocketing the spread,
betting on currency pegs to continue indefinitely, unhedged; nor is it very
different from Western banks' Russian investments, hedging with Russian banks.
None of this has much to do with capitalism per se. It has a lot to do with
foolish financial decisions pressing at the limits, moral hazard, and mispriced
risk.
The answer is not to curtail the flow of global capital.
The problems of the Asian and Russian economies are not primarily due to
"global capitalism," a phrase now sometimes employed as if some
communicable disease were encompassing all of humankind. The fundamental
problems that led to the original crisis were severe imbalances in the Asian
economies that were growing at an unsustainable pace, heavily leveraged risks
with poorly supervised financial institutions, and domestic economic policies
that could not support the exchange rates at which they had pegged, given the
declining inflation in the United States and their higher inflation rates. This
is not just conjecture or opinion but straightforward Economics 101 that has
been taught for decades: A country cannot maintain price stability (or, more
generally, a particular stable inflation rate) and fixed exchange rates if
prices are not stable (or inflation rates differ) elsewhere. Fixed exchange
rates mean domestic monetary policy cannot be independent and vice versa. The only way
to reconcile the dilemma is a far worse course--controlling the free flow of
capital. It is not theoretically, let alone practically, possible to reconcile
fixed exchange rates, independent domestic monetary policy, and free flows of
investment capital; something must give. This was the core problem facing
countries such as Thailand, Indonesia, and South Korea and the primary cause of
their financial crises. Unfortunately, some countries are retreating into
capital controls; surely their need for foreign capital to supply both funds
and the market discipline that properly priced foreign risk capital brings will
be decisive to their long-run prospects.
Clearly, we need a serious reexamination of our international financial
institutions. The combination of changing world economic conditions, mission
creep, and a mixed record of success, including some recent failures, suggests
that a serious rethinking of the purposes, procedures, resources, and
operations of these institutions is an urgent priority. The IMF should be
playing the role of convenor of private lenders, lest lender runs on countries
analogous to depositor runs on banks occur unnecessarily. The role of global
lender of last resort requires a rapid determination of the difference between
illiquidity and insolvency, something not easily done in a political context.
But let us not confuse traditional economic mistakes with fundamental
problems of economic systems. For these economies to retreat back toward
protectionism, capital controls, and even greater centralization of decision
making in government would be a disaster for the mass of humankind. Sensible
improvements in the supervision of their financial institutions and better
central bank policies are the place to start. For example, higher reserve
requirements for short-term deposits and sensible risk-based capital
requirements for financial institutions, if necessary, make a lot more sense
than capital controls or taxes.
CONCLUSION
My conclusion is simple. In addition to their strong moral base in personal
freedom, capitalism and competitive markets work to deliver substantial
economic progress; communism, socialism, even large bureaucratic welfare state
"third ways" do not work. They sap individual incentive, initiative,
and creativity and ultimately cannot deliver sufficiently rising standards of
living to meet the expectations of their citizens for better material lives for
themselves and their progeny. Episodic economic downturns or other perceived
market failures create great opportunity for misplaced permanent expansion
of government's role in the economy.
Clearly, we have learned that government has a number of important roles to
play in our economy and that we must remain vigilant to make sure that it plays only those
necessary roles in the least intrusive manner possible. A consistent
rules-based monetary policy, the lowest possible level and rates of taxation,
less command and control in favor of more flexible market-oriented incentive
regulation, slower growth of government spending including entitlement reform,
and expanded open rules-based trade are surely the lessons of economic history
and would surely be Adam Smith's wise prescription today.
The theme of this year's NABE conference is "Winners and Losers of the
21st Century." Surely a large part of the answer to that implicit question
is "those who can stay closest to the limited government capitalist model
in the face not only of the natural tendency of the government's role in the
economy to grow, but also the incredible impending demographic pressures that
will greatly reinforce this tendency."
The calls for capital controls, greatly expanded taxes and spending, vast
new regulation, extensive industrial policy, and dangerous protectionism
threaten our economic progress and personal liberty. Such calls by pundits and
decriers of capitalism are frequent and occasionally frenetic, both inside and
outside the economics profession. Of course, as economies evolve and conditions
change (e.g., due to changing demography), the role of government based on the
sound market principles enunciated above may reasonably ebb and flow. But
capitalism once again needs its defenders, teachers, exemplars, and champions.
The alternative models have proven historically, intellectually, and
practically bankrupt. We would all be better off if the decriers of capitalism
remained permanently discontented.
No comments:
Post a Comment