Would the Poor Go Barefoot with a Private Shoe
Industry?
By Stephen Davies
It is said that while we may rely on private
initiative to supply “nonessentials,” some things are so important to a decent
life that we cannot trust the vagaries of the competitive market. Some people
would not get the vital product or service. The only solution, supposedly, is
government provision to all, often free of charge. The problems with this
argument, as well as the great benefits of a capitalist economy, are shown by
examining the shoe industry.
Most would agree that shoes are essential to a comfortable
or decent existence. Today even the poorest have shoes, and most people of
modest means have several pairs. Shoes are available in an enormous variety of
types, styles, and colors, at modest prices. It was not always so. In America
just over 150 years ago, shoes were made locally, on an individual basis, by
skilled craftsmen. This may seem idyllic, but it was not. They were extremely
expensive in real terms, so much so that they could even be included in a will.
Most people had only one pair that would be made to last for years. The poor
had no shoes; indeed, being without shoes was one of the classic marks of
poverty.
Things began to change in 1848 with the invention of
the first shoe-sewing machine, and shoemaking moved from the home and small
workshop to factories. However, making shoes was complicated and difficult to
mechanize. In particular, the process of “lasting,” by which leather was molded
to fit a model foot, proved a great challenge. Moreover, the capital cost of
the new machinery was a barrier for many small shoemaking firms.
Two men were to transform this situation in the United
States and subsequently elsewhere. The first was Jan Matzeliger, born in 1852,
an immigrant to the United States from Dutch Guiana (now Suriname), and the son
of a Dutch sea captain and a slave woman. While working in a shoe factory in
Massachusetts, Matzeliger devised a method of mechanizing the lasting process.
He perfected it after years of work and great expense, and obtained capital to
create a production model from two local investors, Charles H. Delnow and
Melville S. Nicholls. Matzeliger got a patent in 1883. His machine cut the cost
of producing a pair of shoes in half. A hand laster could produce no more than
50 pairs a day. Using his machine, one could produce up to 700 pairs.
Matzeliger and his partners set up the Consolidated Lasting Machine
Corporation, in association with two new investors, George A. Brown and the
second main figure in our story, Sidney W. Winslow. Matzeliger sold his patent
rights to the newly formed corporation in exchange for stock, which made him a
wealthy man. He died from tuberculosis in 1889.
Winslow was a business genius. The owner of a small
shoe factory, he transformed the industry by a crucial business innovation. In
1899 he engineered a merger of the three main shoemaking-machinery companies to
form the United Shoe Machinery Corporation (USMC). Instead of selling its
machines, the USMC leased them, which meant that shoe manufacturers no longer
bore the capital cost, including depreciation, of their machinery. USMC also
relieved them of much of the maintenance cost.
The combination of technical invention and business
innovation transformed shoemaking. The cost of shoes fell to a fraction of what
it had been, while the wages of workers more than doubled by 1905. Thanks to
the ease with which producers could obtain the machinery, the industry became
very competitive, which encouraged innovation and kept down costs. This led to
the situation we enjoy today where even the poorest have shoes and the variety
constantly increases. When leasing was applied outside the United States, often
through arrangements with the USMC, the industry was transformed there also.
Let us suppose now that shoes were supplied by
government. We have much evidence of what the result would be. Everyone would
have shoes, but the quality would be poor. There would be almost no variety
(except of the Army kind—two sizes: too large and too small) and certainly no
“fun” shoes. The cost would be high, and there might even be rationing. If some
private supply were allowed, we would have a few private firms providing
high-quality shoes at exorbitant cost to the rich and the ruling elite.
Privatize Shoe Production?
Anyone suggesting that perhaps private enterprise
should produce shoes more widely would be met with the indignant response:
“What! Do you want the poor to go without shoes?” This, of course, is precisely
the situation we face with many services provided predominantly or exclusively
by government, notably education. The point is that once a product is supplied
by government, we find it hard to imagine that it could be provided in any
other way without disastrous results. The assertion that a product is essential
is supposed to end the argument.
The story of the U.S. shoe-machinery industry also
highlights several other points. One is the critical part played in history by
productive and creative individuals whose names are not remembered or lauded in
the way that those of monarchs, politicians, and generals are. Sidney Winslow
did more to benefit millions of people than many “public figures,” yet is almost
forgotten. Another is the way a market economy undercuts prejudice. As a black
man, Jan Matzeliger faced much prejudice, particularly in his social and
religious life. But in the business world his color did not matter, and he had
no trouble finding investors. Only his talent and application mattered.
Finally, the story of the USMC shows the bad effects
of misguided public policy. An enormously successful business, worth over a
billion dollars by 1960 and a model employer, United Shoe was attacked by the
Department of Justice in a famous antitrust case, was broken up in 1968, and
today no longer exists. (Ironically, the leasing policy was targeted as a tool
of USMC’s alleged monopoly practices.) The U.S. shoe manufacturing industry has
also mostly vanished.
So when you put on your shoes or go to buy a pair, be
thankful and remember Jan Matzeliger and Sidney Winslow. Even more, be thankful
that this essential product is not provided by government and imagine what
services provided by the government could be like if the contemporary
equivalents of those two men were let loose on them.
No comments:
Post a Comment