By Anthony de Jasay
Is Standard & Poor, the venerable debt rating
agency, a weapon of mass destruction reminiscent of the pre-Iraq war of George
W. Bush and, like that phantom WMD, perhaps a merely imagined one? The answer
is not easy to call, and has some relevance to how we should evaluate the
strident demands for more and more regulation to correct alleged market
failures.
After some early warnings, early in the new year of 2012 Standard & Poor, in a massive artillery barrage, downgraded the debt rating of 9 of the 17 member states of the Eurozone, some of them by as many as two notches. It did so on a Friday evening, and the majority of the media promised a bloodbath in the bond and stock markets for the following Monday. There was no bloodbath. If anything, markets were firmer. Manifestly, a downgrade by one of the two dominant rating agencies is either a non-event—which sounds very unlikely,—or the nasty, wicked "speculators" have fully anticipated the downgrade and priced it into the markets well before it has actually taken place.
The spectacular mass reduction
in the estimated creditworthiness of the majority of Eurozone countries has set
off a storm of furious indignation and cranky proposals. Some of these were
laughable, some dangerous. It was said that private debt could well be rated by
private agencies, but public debt must be assessed by a public body—needless to
say, a democratic one. An earlier proposal by the Brussels bureaucracy that the
EU should establish its own rating agency to "break the monopoly" of
the private ones, was also revived. Many voices from the Continent of Europe
trotted out the truly lunatic conspiracy theory that the rating agencies, being
undeniably "Anglo-Saxon", are promoting the interests of the USA and
Britain who want to break the euro which, if it survives, would threaten the
"ultra-liberal" domination of the dollar.
Defenders of the agencies say
that blaming them for the bad news they spread is to blame the thermometer for
showing the patient's fever. This, however, is to draw a false analogy; for
what the agencies announce is not a fact, such as the temperature, but their
estimate of the probability that the patient will die prematurely, i.e. that
the debtor state will default on interest or principal at or before the due
date. Seen in this light, downgrading is not malevolent or outrageous, but
logically correct. Only four countries in the Eurozone—Germany, Finland,
Luxemburg and the Netherlands—are judged by S&P to merit the top AAA grade,
and even that may be a shade too generous, for the probability of default is
strictly speaking never zero. AA is about as good as any long-term state
obligation may possibly deserve. Where S&P is clearly blameworthy is the
timing of the mass downgrade. In year after year of ominous overspending, the
notes of most of the euro-states were left peaceably unaltered, only to be
brutally cut just when all these states seem to be more or less convincingly
scrambling to change their ways and reduce their unsustainable budget deficits.
Why downgrade them now when it was not appropriate to do so while they were
still spending as if there were no tomorrow and piling up the debt was only for
petty, mean-spirited accountants to worry about.
A classic fairness rule holds
that you must never kick a man when he is down. An eminent historian of ideas,
John Plamenatz, once said in my hearing that this rule was typical of the silly
English, for the man being down was obviously the most convenient time for
kicking him. S&P must implicitly believe that this was so.
One downgrade that really
looks shockingly timed is the lowering of Italy by two notches to BBB. Italy,
in the last years of the shaming monkey-circus that was the Berlusconi era, (as
the unforgettable Lena Horn used to sing) was "lying face down in the
gutter" and seems not even to mind it too much. During these inglorious
years, its rating remained intact. When late in 2011 it became obvious that
Italy's national debt of 1.7 trillion was too much for her national income of
1.5 to carry, the incorrigible Berlusconi was forced to resign and was replaced
by severely serious Mario Monti who, with admirable courage that only a
non-elected statesman can afford, produced an admirable programme of structural
reforms they fully deserve the hate-word "ultra-liberal", though the
author and the habitual readers of this column would be more comfortable with
calling it simply "liberal" on the original freedom-of-contract sense
of the word. If Mario Monti can defeat organised labour and the vested
interests of business and the professions, Italy should have a brilliant future
over the next few decades. It seems monstrous, then, that S&P are kicking
Italy, not when she is still lying face down in the gutter, but when it is
bravely scrambling to get back on its feet.
Does such infamy help to make
the case for the bizarre Brussels proposal to regulate the rating agencies to
have some public control over what they may or may not say about the
creditworthiness of sovereign states? Such regulation would be a good way for
ensuring that nobody paid any attention any more to what they did say .
If a rating downgrade lastingly depresses the price
of sovereign debt, then it is a self-fulfilling prophecy, for
it makes the refinancing its maturing chunks of the debt more expensive, hence
the budget deficit larger than it would have been if the rating agency had kept
quiet. It is, therefore, a WMD. Since, however, rating agencies will almost
necessarily be created in a free market, and their self-fulfilling prophecy
spoils the natural scheme of things and makes for market failure, such agencies
ought to be outlawed or severely regulated. This, in a nutshell, is the view if
much of the Brussels bureaucracy and of semi-educated European commentators. It
is becoming parrot-talk.
Remember, however, that the
rating is not fact-finding, but a forecast. It is a judgment inspired by facts,
like any other forecast. There are literally hundreds of such forecasts
flooding the public forum every month, poured out by the OECD, the IMF, the
ECB, the Brussels Commission, government agencies, universities, non-profit
research organisations and private consultants. Many of them employ more
economic brainpower than S&P or Moody. The institutional investors who make
the bond markets routinely take some notice of the forthcoming forecasts. The
cleverest among them may even anticipate the rating agencies, selling bonds prior
to a downgrade and buying them back after it. But no market participant has
good cause to believe that the agencies are any more prescient than the other
forecasters. Why, then, do we assume that they are more powerful than the
average of the others?
Much of the answer lies in one
word: they have an ally. It is a non-market one, not a spontaneous growth but a
political and institutional artifact: a legal rule, or self-regulation adopted
to forestall it. Governments, believing that they are doing good, forbid
certain types of investors, notably pension funds and insurance companies, to
buy and hold debt securities that the agencies do not rate highly enough. Even
non-regulated funds will conform to such rules because the fund manager may be
more interested in looking prudent and blameless in case of accidents than in
maximising the return to the fund's owners. Such principal-agent conflicts may
be the secondary effects of government regulation.
Once a country's sovereign
debt comes to be graded below the critical level set by regulation, or even
threatens to be set below it, the regulated funds must liquidate their holdings
as an automatic knee-jerk reaction. The market, in other words, is artificially
programmed as a safety-first mechanism and not, as a flawless market is
supposed to act, mechanism for balancing risk against reward, as risk and
reward are perceived from day to day by the marginal buyers and sellers who are
trying to do the best they can and are under no constraint to jump when the
rating agencies say "jump". The ones who jump mostly do so, not
because they fear the agencies as weapons of mass destruction, but because the
regulators say so and public opinion discourages contrarian judgment.
No comments:
Post a Comment