By DANIEL HANNAN
How could so
many clever people get it so wrong? The
flaws in the euro project are not just clear with hindsight; they were visible
at the outset and were widely pointed out. It was never going to be possible to
jam widely divergent economies into a single monetary policy. It was plainly
reckless to invite Italy and Greece to join the new currency when their
government debt was at twice the permitted level of 60 per cent of GDP. Plenty
of doubters said so at the time. Yet, in every national parliament, in every
central bank, in every university faculty, in every television editorial
conference, there was a collective suspension of disbelief.
Why? What were they thinking? If you listen carefully to what Euro-integrationists were saying when the single currency was launched, you hear a subtext. It's not so much that they liked the euro, it's that they disliked the people who opposed it. Listen, for example to Charles Kennedy in 2002:
The euro, despite gloomy predictions from anti-Europeans, has proved to be a success. We cannot afford to be isolated from our biggest and closest trading partner any longer.
Or
to Ken Clarke:
The reality of the euro has exposed the absurdity of many anti-European scares while increasing the public thirst for information. Public opinion is already changing as people can see the success of the new currency on the mainland.
For
such men, the issue was never really economic, or even political, but tribal.
Having defined the question, in their own minds, as a Kulturkampf between
sensible progressives and ignorant bigots, they became more or less
uninterested in the facts.
The
extraordinary thing is that many euro-enthusiasts are still at it, quite
unabashed by how things have turned out. Here, for example, is the historian
Norman Davies in the Financial Times a couple of weeks ago:
‘How marvellous,' they chortle in the Tory clubs; ‘the busybodies of Brussels are meeting their come-uppance. After all, those ghastly Greeks who cooked the books to enter Euroland in the first place are sure to be cooking them again with an eye to ever larger bail-outs. Greece will push French banks down the chute first; but German banks won't avoid it, and together they'll finish Italy off. With luck, Italy will suck Spain into the abyss; Portugal will follow Spain, and Ireland Portugal. Just think of it! Those Irish traitors from 1922 will get their deserts! Terrific!'
Then
continental banks lock their doors and the cash machines dry up. Minestrone
kitchens appear on the streets of Rome. Spanish bullrings house the destitute.
The bridges of Paris fill with rough sleepers. Weeks and months pass free of
money. Europeans relearn the art of barter. When the cash flow stutters back,
machines distribute drachmas again, the franc nouvel and the peseta nueva. Yet
Britain's latterday Blimps will still not be satisfied. They hanker for the
whole hog; before we pull up the drawbridge, they say, the EU itself must
vanish.
For
what it's worth, I have yet to meet a British eurosceptic who is enjoying the
economic turmoil on our doorstep. It is plainly in our interest that the
eurozone-which takes 40 per cent of our exports, and comprises our allies and
friends-should flourish. That's precisely why we are alarmed at the readiness
of eurocrats to sacrifice their peoples' prosperity so as to keep their
monetary union together.
Not
that Norman Davies is much interested in what eurosceptics actually think. One
of the oddities of the whole debate is that euroenthusiastic commentators who
are quick to spot prejudice in others when it comes to racism, sexism or
xenophobia are quite unable to detect it in themselves when it comes to people
who don't share their Weltanschauung. (By the way, Professor Davies,
one usesnouvel before a masculine noun beginning with a vowel – le
nouvel an, but le nouveau franc. When loftily dismissing people as
anti-Europeans, it's a good idea to get your own French right.)
None
of this would matter if it were simply an academic debate. The trouble is that
the people running the EU refuse to learn anything from their errors. Since the
crisis began four years ago, they have had only one response: massive loans.
They have reacted to the failure of each bailout by accelerating the policy,
until it has acquired a momentum of its own, like a runaway train:
bailout-and-borrow, bailout-and-borrow, bailout-and-borrow.
Why
this mulish determination to stick with a strategy that is impoverishing
Europe? Supporters of the project have taken to offering the old
cure-would-be-worse-than-the-disease shtick. They no longer dare argue that the
euro has brought benefits — two thirds of the citizens who use it believe it
has made them poorer, according to Eurobarometer — insisting instead that
leaving would be impractical.
To
British ears, such claims are eerily familiar. When it became clear that the
Exchange Rate Mechanism, the euro's baleful predecessor, was wrecking our
economy, the Establishment lined up to argue that, whatever the flaws in the
system, we now had no option but to stick with it. Pulling out, declared John
Major, would be "the inflationary option, the devaluer's option, a
betrayal of the future of our country". In the event, of course, Britain's
recovery began the day we left the ERM and continued for a decade and a half
before Gordon Brown blew it away.
Yes,
there would be practical difficulties with returning to national currencies,
but none would be insurmountable. By definition, all the countries in the euro
have recently managed precisely such a changeover: that's how they joined in
the first place. Oddly, I don't remember any eurocrats at that time droning on
about the huge costs and complexities of having to replace your banknotes. And,
indeed, the switch would be easier now than it was a decade ago, because more
money is digitised, and banknotes represent a smaller proportion of the currency
in circulation.
Nor
should leaving a currency union be any more complicated than joining one. I
asked a Slovakian economist the other day how his country had managed the
monetary transition when it divorced the Czech Republic. "Very
easily," he replied. "One Friday, after the markets had closed, the
head of our central bank phoned round all the banks and told them that, over
the weekend, someone from his office would come round with a stamp to put on
all their banknotes, and that, until the new notes and coins came into
production, those stamped notes would be Slovakia's legal tender. On the Monday
morning, we had a new currency."
Why
not do the same today? Because, to repeat, the euro was never about the
economics. As Angela Merkel told the Bundestag in October:
Nobody should take for granted another 50 years of peace and prosperity in Europe, and that's why I say, if the euro fails, Europe fails. We have a historical obligation: to protect by all means Europe's unification process begun by our forefathers after centuries of hatred and bloodshed.
Put
in those terms, of course, the issue is literally beyond argument. If you
oppose the euro, Mrs Merkel suggests, you're in favour of war.The trouble is
that, on any objective measure, the euro is stoking rather than soothing
national antagonisms. Relations between Germany and Greece haven't been so poor
since-well, since the Second World War.
The
reason, of course, is that people in both countries see politicians lining up
with the Brussels elites against their own constituents. The few national
leaders who dare challenge the EU risk being overthrown.
George
Papandreou did something unforgiveable in the eyes of Brussels when he proposed
a referendum on the loans-for-austerity package. Eurocrats dislike and distrust
popular democracy. Referendums at any time are frowned on; but a referendum
when the euro was teetering on the edge was seen as the height of selfishness
and ingratitude. Within a week, Papandreou had been forced out.
A
similar thing happened in Italy. Observing the EU's reaction to the Greek
crisis, Silvio Berlusconi calculated that Eurocrats would do anything to
prevent the break-up of the euro: if his austerity measures were insufficient,
Brussels would come up with the extra cash. Accordingly, he let it be known
that he was relaxed about whether or not Italy should remain in the euro. If
the Brussels elites wanted to preserve their continental currency, he implied,
they would have to pay for it. "Since the euro was adopted", he
breezily told his countrymen, "most Italians have become poorer."
Once those words were spoken, he, too, was doomed. An EU official at the Cannes
summit was quoted as saying: "We're on our way to moving out
Berlusconi." Five days later, il Cavaliere had been forced to announce his
resignation.
The
funny thing is that neither of the ousted premiers was a eurosceptic.
Papandreou, indeed, was a federalist. Their crime, rather, was to pay too much
attention to their electorates. Leninists had a term for people who, while
committed Bolsheviks, none the less behaved in a way which endangered the
movement. They were known as "objectively counter-revolutionary". The
supreme counter-revolutionary act, in the EU, is to ask voters what they want.
If
you think I'm exaggerating, consider the way the EU deals with referendum
results when they go the "wrong" way. Ponder how Brussels swatted
aside the verdicts of the ballot box in France, the Netherlands and Ireland. As
José Manuel Barroso put it last year:
"Governments are not always right. If governments were always right we would not have the situation that we have today. Decisions taken by the most democratic institutions in the world are very often wrong."
People
sometimes talk of the EU's democratic deficit as if it were accidental. In
fact, it is essential to the whole design. Having lived through the 1920s and
1930s, the founders had little faith in democracy — especially the plebiscitary
democracy which they saw as a prelude to demagoguery and fascism. They were
therefore unapologetic about vesting supreme power in the hands of appointed
commissioners who were to be invulnerable to public opinion. They were
disarmingly honest, too, about the fact that their dream of common European
statehood would never be realised if successive transfers of power to Brussels
had to be approved by the national electorates.
The
euro was the culmination of their scheme. It would never have got off the
ground had the decision been subject to national referendums. The only two
countries to vote on whether to join — Denmark and Sweden — opted emphatically
to keep their national currencies. Nor would the bailouts be approved today by
the voters of the contributing states; nor, indeed, would the austerity
packages be agreed by voters in the recipient states. In order to pursue these
policies, two regimes have had to be replaced with what are called
"national governments" — although their sole purpose is, of course,
to carry out programmes that their nations reject.
These
"national governments" are headed by "technocrats" —
meaning, in this instance, the euro-apparatchiks whose policies created the
mess in the first place. The new Italian prime minister, Mario Monti, is a
former European Commissioner; his Greek counterpart, Lucas Papademos, a former
Vice-President of the European Central Bank. Mr Papademos, indeed, was running
the Greek central bank when the calamitous decision was made to join the euro
with twice the permitted debt level. In recent weeks, the EU has made explicit
what was implicit all along. Bureaucrats in Brussels now deal directly with
bureaucrats in the stricken peripheral states. The people and their elected
representatives have been cut out. Greece is now as much a satrapy of the
European Commission as ever it was of the Ottomans. Its people are learning at
first hand that you can have European integration or you can have full
democracy, but you can't have both.
While
most people recognise that the EU is undemocratic in its own structures, few
understand the extent to which it subverts the internal democracy of its constituent
states. In order to participate in an inherently unpopular project, the 27
national governments are repeatedly obliged to defy their own electorates — or
face the consequences.
The
downfalls of Papandreou and Berlusconi are eerily reminiscent of that of
Margaret Thatcher. She, too, was an elected national leader who had got on the
wrong side of the Brussels machine. Her emphatic rejection of Jacques Delors's
scheme for federal unification in 1990 was followed by the famous
"ambush" at the EU Rome summit, when she was left looking unprepared
and isolated. That was the trigger for British europhiles to move against her.
It's
true, of course, that all three leaders were already unpopular: Thatcher
because of the poll tax, Papandreou because of the austerity measures and
Berlusconi because of innumerable scandals. None the less, it is sobering to
think that the Italian premier, having weathered allegations of corruption and
mafia links, of bribery and underage sex, having shrugged off investigations by
(at his own count) 789 prosecuting magistrates, having survived in office
longer than any leader since Mussolini, should have been felled in the end by
the EU.
Borrowing
a felicitious phrase from C.S. Lewis, I think of the phenomenon as the EU's
"hideous strength". In his science fiction novel of that name, Lewis
tells the story of a diabolical plot to take over Britain, which takes the
guise of an apparently beneficent bureaucracy called the National Institute for
Co-ordinated Experiments: NICE. The functionaries of NICE have deep pockets,
offer generous salaries, and are vague but upbeat about their aims. They
succeed in subverting one institution after another.
The
EU has a similar power to purchase the loyalty of NGOs, charities, business
organisations, local councils and, above all, governing parties. Again and
again, it persuades politicians at the domestic level to act against their
national, party and personal interests for the sake of Europe. To give only the
most recent example, all three British party leaders put out a three-line Whip
against the parliamentary motion calling for a referendum on EU membership —
despite the fact that 67 per cent of voters wanted their MPs to support the
resolution, and despite the fact that all three parties were promising
referendums on one aspect or another of European integration before the general
election.
The
truth is that the EU, run by its 27-member politburo, is barely more democratic
than the "German Democratic Republic" or the "Democratic
Federation of Yugoslavia". While its member nations are all, in
themselves, parliamentary democracies, Brussels functionaries fear and resent
public opinion, or "populism" as they call it in their peculiar
argot. Their attitude might not be quite so objectionable if the technocrats
actually displayed any real expertise. Yet, time and again, they have been
shown to be wrong, the mass of ordinary voters right.
Rarely
has this been more obvious than in their response to the financial crisis. Most
of us know that the last thing an indebted friend needs is more loans. Most of
us understand that if you're in debt, you should cut back on spending, not go
on a binge. Most of us can see that if jamming disparate economies into a
single currency isn't working, the answer is less integration, not more. Yet
these truisms are quite lost on the European elites.
The
leaders of the eurozone are, of course, free to make their own mistakes. If
they want to inflict penury and emigration on their southern members, and
perpetual tax rises on their northern members, that is their prerogative. If
they are prepared to pay a ruinous price to keep the euro — or, more precisely,
to ask their peoples to pay, since eurocrats are exempt from national taxes —
that's up to them.
What
I find inexplicable is that the United Kingdom should be investing political
capital — let alone actual capital — in supporting the project. At the time of
writing, Britain is on the hook for £12.5 billion in the Greek, Irish and
Portuguese bailouts — a colossal sum even in these wastrel times, equivalent to
£500 for every household in the land. To put it in context, consider that all
the spending cuts made by the Coalition in its first 12 months in office
amounted to £6.2 billion. Yet, if we are drawn into the Italian crisis, the
bills will be far higher: ministers talk of Britain injecting a further £40
billion through the IMF.
In
justifying these subsidies, ministers tell us that the prosperity of the
eurozone is in Britain's interest, and so it is. Yet it is now surely clear that
the euro is a recessionary device. The survival of the single currency and the
economic success of its constituent members, far from being synonymous, are
becoming incompatible. Britain, in short, is being made to pay for the
privilege of impoverishing its neighbours.
What
the devil are we thinking? According to the most thorough study so far,
conducted by the Centre for Economics and Business Research, Britain's
interests would be better served by the break-up of the euro than by its
maintenance. There would be short-term pain followed, after about 30 months, by
a higher rate of growth. Yet the Coalition continues to insist that the
survival of the euro is an essential British interest. How has the Conservative
Party moved so swiftly from "save the pound" to "save the
euro"?
The
short answer is that it won office. It is difficult, until you encounter it at
first hand, to grasp the intensity of the euro-fanaticism in the civil service
and, most especially, the Foreign and Commonwealth Office. The guiding principle
of our Brussels mandarins is that they must always be present at the table:
being human, they have an understandable tendency to conflate their own
influence with the national interest.
A
minister who seriously challenged the basis of our relationship with the EU
would be declaring war on the permanent apparat — a war that would consume his
energies for an entire parliamentary mandate. Such ministers are, of course,
rare. Which is why, in every EU member state, euroscepticism has so far been an
exclusively opposition phenomenon. In most EU states, the governing cadres are
as steeped in Keynesian economics as in euro-enthusiasm. Government employees
are perhaps naturally sympathetic to doctrines which encourage state
intervention, and their reaction to the financial crisis was the same as their
reaction to all crises: to increase spending. As Mark Twain observed, if all
you have is a hammer, everything starts to look like a nail.
We
can now see where such profligacy has led Europe — and, indeed, where it has
led the United Kingdom. Our treasury is empty, our credit exhausted, and we are
reduced to relying on inflation to erode a deficit which we daren't tackle with
spending cuts. Yet, broke as we are, it is seriously being proposed by our
immaculately educated officials and ministers that we borrow billions more in
order to prop up a currency union which is asphyxiating its participants. My
masters, are you mad?
No comments:
Post a Comment