By Steven Horwitz
Suppose on some sunny
afternoon in a large city somewhere in the western world, a man discovers on
awaking from a two-hour nap that several hundred car accidents had occurred in
the city while he slept. He wonders why. First he considers the possibility
that the weather was the cause, but the gorgeous afternoon sun pushes that
thought aside. The odds of many hundreds of cars having simultaneous
mechanical problems seems infinitesimally small, so he rules that out as
well. He ponders the question further and eventually asks himself whether
the drivers in that fair city just had a bout of group psychosis or mass
delusion. The odds of that also seem pretty low.As his brain slowly awakens, he stumbles across the likely culprit: Something must be wrong with the traffic lights. He concludes that the lights are not working, leaving the drivers to figure out how to negotiate the intersections on their own. Wouldn’t that, he wonders, cause many accidents? He turns to his wife and suggests that explanation. She replies: “If you came to a traffic light and saw it was not working at all, wouldn’t you slow down and proceed cautiously? In fact, after Hurricane Katrina didn’t people in New Orleans just treat broken traffic lights like four-way stops, without explicit direction to do so?” Our fellow acknowledges his wife’s insightfulness and continues to ponder.
Soon it hits him: It’s not that the traffic lights
were not functioning at all, but rather they
were all green. If all the lights were green, drivers would
have no reason to think the lights were not working and would proceed through
every intersection — with the result being the hundreds of accidents. It
strikes our fellow that not only do green lights mean go, they also mean that
the cross-traffic has stopped. This is how traffic lights do their job of
coordinating the plans of drivers on both streets.
Reckless Drivers Blamed
Our man begins to watch the coverage of the accidents
on TV, where breathless commentators are blaming the crashes on the irrational
and reckless behavior of drivers. He thinks: “That’s not
fair. They did not act irrationally; they simply responded
reasonably to a signal whose meaning they’ve long understood.” As he gets
angrier about the blame being placed on the drivers, he realizes that the
irrationality that caused the crashes was not in the actors but in
the traffic signals. When traffic signals don’t tell the
truth, in this case that the cross-traffic has stopped, even the most rational,
cautious drivers will get into accidents at intersections. He is stunned
that the TV commentators can’t see this. In despair he goes back to
sleep, hoping it was all a dream.
Not only was it not a dream, it was the reality of the
post-2001 boom that generated the financial crisis and Great Recession.
The Austrian economist Israel Kirzner has long used traffic lights as an
analogy for prices. In the case of the boom and bust, the key price was the
interest rate. In a free market, interest rates and the banking system
coordinate the plans of the cross-traffic of lender-savers and
borrower-spenders. If saving increases, it means consumers are more
willing to wait for goods. Their saving leads banks to offer lower
interest rates, providing a traffic signal (and an incentive) for borrowers to
borrow for longer-term projects that match the greater patience of
consumers. If consumers are more impatient and save less, banks
raise rates, leading borrowers to go more short term to match this
preference. Each side’s behavior is consistent with the other’s, thanks
to the traffic-signal role of the interest rate.
Central Bank Tampering
When the central bank intervenes, however, it turns
all the lights green. Expansionary monetary policy provides loanable
funds to banks, which enables them to lower rates as
if there were more saving. However, that saving is an
illusion; consumers have not become more patient.
With lower rates, borrowers find longer-term projects more profitable and
so divert resources to them and away from others. The problem,
of course, is that consumers do not in fact wish to wait longer than they did
before. So producer-borrowers invest in longer-term projects while
consumer-savers continue to want relatively shorter term ones. This, like
traffic patterns with broken signals, is not sustainable and will eventually
lead to the economic equivalent of car crashes: the onset of a recession as
this discoordination is revealed.
Of course robust economies can mask underlying
discoordination for a fairly long time before it is revealed. A city
suffering through a plague of all-green traffic lights sees a more immediate
and visible result.
Like our drivers, borrowers were not irrational during
the boom. They simply responded rationally to an irrational signal.
The source of that irrational signal was the Federal Reserve System. The
next time a friend blames the boom and bust on irrational investors, you might
recall our protagonist’s city and say: “The irrationality, dear friend, is
not in our markets but in our government, that is, the central bank.”
No comments:
Post a Comment