If you start in the city center of Nogales Santa Cruz
and walk south for a while, at some point you see houses become much more run
down, streets turn decrepit. You have crossed the Mexican border into Nogales,
Sonora. Though the two cities are made of the same cloth and were once united,
now there are sharp differences between the two. Those in the north are about
three times as rich, have access to much better health care, stay in school
much longer and of course take part in a much more democratic political process
than their cousins in the south. The differences between the two halves of
Nogales are a micro, tiny version of huge differences in prosperity and living
standards we see around the world. Take Mexico as a whole, for example: it has
less than one quarter of the GDP per capita of the United States. Take Peru; it
has about one seventh of the GDP per capita of the United States. Or take
Ethiopia, Haiti, Somalia or the Congo, each of has less than one thirtieth of
the GDP per capita of the United States.
Several pundits and journalists will tell you that these are due to geographic factors condemning some areas to poverty, or to cultural factors making some people lazy or not sufficiently inquisitive, or to the fact that some countries have better leaders or received better policy advice and know what to do about their economy. But these are all wrong and as unhelpful for understanding the gulf that separates the rich from poor around the world as they are irrelevant for understanding the differences between the two Nogaleses. Of course what divides the two Nogaleses is not geography (they have the same geography); it is not culture (according to any reasonable definition, they have the same culture); and it is not any sort of wisdom on the part of the leaders of Nogales, Santa Cruz. What divides the two is the border, which creates the very different sets of institutions to the north and the south.
To understand what these institutions are and what
they do, take another society divided by a border. South and North Korea. The
people of South Korea have living standards similar to those of Portugal and
Spain. To the north, in the so-called Democratic People's Republic of Korea, or
North Korea, living standards are akin to those of a sub-Saharan African
country, about one tenth of average living standards in South Korea. The health
of North Koreans is in an even worse state; the average North Korean can expect
to live ten years less than their cousins to the south of the 38th parallel.
These striking differences are not ancient. In fact
they did not exist prior to the end of the Second World War. But after 1945 the
different governments in the north and the south adopted very different ways of
organizing their economies. South Korea was led and its early economic and
political institutions were shaped by the Harvard and Princeton educated,
staunchly anti-Communist Syngman Rhee, with significant support from the United
States. Rhee was elected president in 1948. Forged in the midst of the Korean
War and against the threat of communism spreading to the south of the 38th
parallel, South Korea was no democracy. Both Rhee and his equally famous
successor, General Park Chung-Hee, secured their places in history books as
authoritarian presidents. But both governed a market economy where private
property was recognized, and after 1961 Park effectively threw the weight of
the state behind rapid economic growth channeling credit and subsidies to firms
that were successful.
The situation north of the 38th parallel was very
different. Kim Il-Sung, a leader of anti-Japanese communist partisans during
the Second World War, established himself as dictator by 1947, and with the
help of the Soviet Union, introduced a rigid form of centrally planned economy.
Private property was outlawed and markets were banned. Freedoms were curtailed
not only in the market place, but in every sphere of North Koreans'
lives---except for those that happened to be part of the very small ruling
elite around Kim Il-Sung, and later around his son and successor Kim Jong-Il.
It should be no surprise that the economic fortunes of
South and North Korea diverged sharply. Kim Il-Sung's command economy soon
proved to be a disaster. Detailed statistics are not available from North
Korea, which is a secretive state to say the least. Nonetheless, available
evidence confirms what we know from the all too often recurring famines: not
only did industrial production fail to take off but North Korea in fact
experienced a collapse in agricultural productivity. Lack of private property
meant that few had incentives to invest or exert effort to increase or even
maintain productivity. The stifling repressive regime was inimical to
innovation and adoption of new technologies. But Kim Il-Sung, his son and
successor, the "dear leader" Kim Jong-Il, and their cronies had no
intention to reform the system, or to introduce private property, markets,
private contracts, and economic and political freedoms. North Korea continues
to stagnate economically, and there is no sign that anything will be different
under the new "dear leader" Kim Jong-un.
Meanwhile in the south economic institutions encouraged investment and trade. South Korean politicians invested in education, achieving high rates of literacy and schooling. South Korean companies were quick to take advantage of the relatively educated population, the policies encouraging investment and industrialization, the export markets, and the transfer of technology. South Korea became one of East Asia's `Miracle Economies,' one of the most rapidly growing nations in the world. By the late 1990s, in just about half a century, South Korean growth and North Korean stagnation led to a tenfold gap between the two halves of this once-united country---imagine what a difference a couple centuries could make. The economic disaster of North Korea, which not only prevented growth but led to the starvation of millions, when placed against the South Korean economic success, is striking: neither culture nor geography nor ignorance can explain the divergent paths of North and South Korea.
Meanwhile in the south economic institutions encouraged investment and trade. South Korean politicians invested in education, achieving high rates of literacy and schooling. South Korean companies were quick to take advantage of the relatively educated population, the policies encouraging investment and industrialization, the export markets, and the transfer of technology. South Korea became one of East Asia's `Miracle Economies,' one of the most rapidly growing nations in the world. By the late 1990s, in just about half a century, South Korean growth and North Korean stagnation led to a tenfold gap between the two halves of this once-united country---imagine what a difference a couple centuries could make. The economic disaster of North Korea, which not only prevented growth but led to the starvation of millions, when placed against the South Korean economic success, is striking: neither culture nor geography nor ignorance can explain the divergent paths of North and South Korea.
So what explains the divergence between South and
North Korea and the gap between the two Nogaleses and those between the United
States, and Mexico, Peru, Ethiopia, Haiti Somalia, or the Congo? The answer is
institutions. Countries differ in their economic success because of their
different institutions, the rules influencing how the economy works and
incentives that motivate people. Imagine the lives of teenagers in North and
South Korea and what they expect from life. Those in the North grow up in
poverty, without adequate education to prepare them for skilled work,
entrepreneurial initiative and creativity. Much of the education they receive
at school is pure propaganda, meant to shore up the legitimacy of the regime.
There are few books or pencils let alone computers. After finishing school
everyone has to go into the army for ten years. These teenagers know that they
will not be able to own property, start a business, or improve their living
standards even if many people engage illegally in private economic activities
to make a living. They also know that they will not have legal access to
markets where they can utilize their skills or use their earnings to purchase
the goods that they need and desire. They are even unsure about what kind of
human rights they will have.
Those in the South obtain a good education, and face
incentives that encourage them to exert effort and excel in their chosen
vocation. South Korea is a market economy, built on private property. South
Korean teenagers know that, if successful as entrepreneurs or workers, one day
they can enjoy the fruits of their investments and efforts; they can increase
their living standards, buy consumer goods, cars, houses and health care.
In the South, the state supports economic activity and
upholds law and order. So it is possible for entrepreneurs to borrow money from
banks and financial markets, for foreign companies to enter into partnerships
with South Korean firms, for individuals to take up mortgages to buy houses. In
the South by and large, you are free to open any business you like. In the
North you are not, though you can do so illegally and covertly as many people
do to avoid starvation. In the South you can hire workers, sell your product or
services, and spend your money in the marketplace in whichever way you want. In
the North there are only black markets. These different rules are the
institutions under which North and South Koreans live.
We call institutions, such as those in South Korea or
in the United States, inclusive. These uphold private property,
enforce law and order and contracts, encourage and support economic activity,
allow entry of new businesses and permit the functioning of markets are
inclusive economic institutions. They encourage the participation of most
people in economic activities that best make use of their talents and skills.
They also distribute political power more evenly in society and it is this
pluralistic distribution of political power that makes these institutions work.
Institutions, like those in North Korea or the Congo,
are extractive. They fail to enforce property rights, contracts,
and law and order; take away economic freedoms and coerce people into
occupations that they don't want; erect prohibitive entry barriers; and involve
the state intervening to distort markets and economic incentives rather than
supporting these and providing public services are extractive economic
institutions. They are supported by Communist Party's tight control over
political power. The term extractive stems from the fact that such economic
institutions are often shaped by those who control political power to extract
resources from the rest of the society.
The contrast of South and North Korea illustrates a
general principle: inclusive economic institutions foster economic activity,
productivity growth and economic prosperity, while extractive economic
institutions generally fail to do so. Property rights are central, since only
those who have secure property rights will be willing to invest and increase
productivity. A farmer, for example, who expects his output to be stolen,
expropriated or entirely taxed away would have little incentive to work, let
alone any incentive to undertake investments and innovations. But extractive
economic institutions do exactly that and fail to uphold property rights of
workers, farmers, traders and businessmen.
Inclusive institutions are not just made of secure and
enforced property rights for a narrow elite, but require both such rights to be
available to the majority of the population and the political power in society
to be distributed evenly to match this. In 1680, the English government
conducted a census of the population of its West Indian colony of Barbados. It
revealed that of the total population on the island of around 60,000, almost
39,000 were African slaves who were the property of the remaining one third of
the population. Indeed, they were mostly the property of the largest 175 sugar
planters who also owned most of the land. These large planters had secure and
well enforced property rights over their land and even over their slaves. If
one planter wanted to sell slaves to another, he could do so and expect a court
to enforce such a sale or any other contract he was a party of. For one thing,
of the 40 judges and justices of the peace on the island, 29 of them were large
planters. For another, all of the eight most senior military officials were
large planters. Despite well-defined, secure and enforced property rights and
contracts for the island's elite, Barbados had highly extractive economic
institutions since two thirds of the population were slaves with no access to
education, economic opportunities and no ability or incentive to use their
talents or skills. Inclusive economic institutions require secure property
rights and economic opportunities not just for the elite but for a broad
cross-section of society.
Our thesis is that both poverty and prosperity are
created by economic and political incentives, and these incentives are shaped
by institutions. South Nogales, Sonora and North Korea are poor because its
inhabitants have limited economic opportunities, a poor state of infrastructure
to build on, not enough education because of the poor state of public schools,
and little security that if they work hard and invest they'll be able to enjoy
the fruits of this. They are relatively poor not by choice, their poverty has
been created by the institutions they live under. Crucially, these institutions
are not in place by accident, but have their own logic. The institutions that
inhabitants of South Nogales, some are live under have been forged by Mexican
elites and politicians who have designed a system for their own benefit at the
expense of the vast majority of the citizens of Mexico. The situation in North
Korea is no different. Extractive institutions have been created and are kept
in place for the benefit of the narrow elite dominating the Communist Party,
and it is those who prosper while scores of North Koreans perish in famines.
The recent events in North Africa and the Middle East
highlight of the importance of understanding these additional dynamics and the
central role of politics plays. The 'Arab spring' had already swept the
Tuinisian President Bin Ali from power by early 2011, and then spread to the
rest of the region. Longtime Egyptian president Husni Mubarak was ousted soon
after Bin Ali. Muammar al-Qadhdhafi's 42 year reign in Libya came to an end in
August 2011. The roots of discontent in these countries are economic, political
and social. The average Egyptian, for example, has an income level of around 12%
of the average citizen of the US, can expect to live 10 years fewer and 20% of
the population is in dire poverty. The general population has been repressed
and excluded from political power for generations. The root cause of these
differences has nothing to do with geography, culture or policy mistakes. They
are institutional. And the protesters in Tahrir Square understood this in
demanding not just handouts or concessions, but fundamental political change.
While they underscore the role of politics in shaping
the trajectories of nations, these events also pose challenging questions: do
we expect democracy or extremism to triumph in Egypt? Have the events in Tahrir
Square changed the nature of politics irrevocably or will a similar economic
and political structure reemerge under a different guise? Will the same
tensions erupt similarly in other parts of the region such as Bahrain, Jordan
and Saudi Arabia? It is ultimately for answering such questions, and gauging
their consequences for economic and social progress around the world, that we
need to understand the institutional roots and the politics of prosperity and
poverty.
No comments:
Post a Comment