By Philipp Bagus
As I discussed recently, the costs and risks of maintaining the eurozone system are already immense and rising. So is an exit
possible? Intuitively, the exit from the euro should be as easy as the
entrance. Joining and leaving the club should be equally simple. Leaving is
just undoing what was done before. Indeed, many popular articles discuss the
prospects of an exit of countries such as Greece or Germany.[1] However, other voices have rightly argued that
there are important exit problems. Some authors even argue that these problems
would make an exit from the euro virtually impossible. Thus, Eichengreen (2010)
states, "The decision to join the euro area is effectively
irreversible." Similarly, Porter (2010) argues that the large costs of an
exit would make it highly unlikely. In the following we address the alleged
exit problems.
Legal Problems
The Maastricht Treaty does not provide for a mechanism to exit the European
Monetary Union (EMU). Thus, several authors maintain that an exit from
the euro would constitute a breach of the treaties (Cotterill 2011, Procter and
Thieffry 1998, Thieffry 2011, Anthanassiou 2009).[2] In an ECB working paper from 2009 Anthanassiou claims that a
country that exits the EMU would have to leave the EU as well. As the Lisbon Treaty allows for
secession from the EU, withdrawal from the EU would be the only way to get rid
of the euro.
The solution to this legal problem could be an exit from both the EMU and EU with an immediate reentering of the EU. This procedure could be negotiated beforehand. In the case of a net contributor to the EU budget such as Germany, the country would probably not face any problem getting immediately readmitted to the EU.
In any case, the referral to the Maastricht Treaty
when discussing the legal possibility of exit is intriguing, because the
Maastricht Treaty, especially the "no-bailout clause," has been
violated through the bailouts of Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. The European Financial
Stability Facility effectively
serves to guarantee debts of other nations, not to mention the plans to
introduce eurobonds.
In addition, the European Central Bank has violated
the spirit of the Maastricht Treaty by purchasing debt of troubled nations. It
seems to be a justification, if not an obligation, to leave the euro after the
conditions for its existence have been violated.[3] Indeed, the German Constitutional Court ruled in
1993 that Germany could leave the euro if the goals of monetary stability were
not attained (Scott 1998, p. 215). After the last couple of years, it is clear
that the eurozone and the euro are far from stable. Apart from these
considerations it should be noted that a sovereign state can repudiate the
treaty (Deo, Donovan, and Hatheway 2011).
Another legal problem results from the possible
redenomination of contracts in the wake of an exit from the euro. A government
may redenominate euro contracts into the new currency (applying lexmonetae — the state determines its own
currency). It may do so without problems if the contracts were contracted in
its territory or under its law. But what about private and public bonds issued
in foreign countries? How would foreign courts rule (Scott 1998, p. 224)?
Imagine a German company that sold a bond in Paris.
Will the bond be paid back in euros or in the new currency if Germany leaves
the euro? The French court would probably decide that it can or must be paid
back in euros.[4] Possibly also the European Court of Justice
would rule on such issues. Thus, in the case of an exit, there would be some
uncertainty caused by court settlements. There may be one-time losses or
profits for the involved parties. However, it is hard to see why these court rulings
would constitute important disturbances or insurmountable obstacles for a euro
exit.[5]
Introduction Costs
An exit from the euro may imply the issuing of a new
national currency. This involves the costs of printing new notes, melting new
coins, exchanging vendor machines, etc. There are also logistic costs
exchanging the new currency against the old one. These costs are not higher
than the costs of introducing the euro. The costs for introducing the euro in
Austria have been estimated at €1.45 billion euros or around 0.5 percent of
GDP.[6]
Wage Inflation and Higher Interest Rates
Sometimes it is argued that peripheral countries with
uncompetitive wages could just exit the euro and magically solve all their
problems. Greece, for instance, suffers from too-high wages mainly because
there is no free labor market. Labor unions have caused wages to be too high.
The resulting unemployment had been attenuated by government deficit spending
and debt accumulation made possible by the Eurosystem. The Greek government employed people at high wages,
paid unemployment benefits and retired people early with high pensions.
As strong labor unions prevent wages from falling to
recuperate competitiveness, some people recommend that Greece exit the euro,
depreciate the currency, and thereby increase competitiveness. This argument
contains a problem. If labor unions remain strong, they may simply demand wage
increases to compensate for higher import prices (Eichengreen 2010, p. 8). Such
a compensatory increase in wages would eliminate all advantages from
depreciation.[7] The exit would have to be accompanied by a
reform of the labor market in order to improve competitiveness. In any case,
after an exit from the EMU, the Greek government could no longer use EMU
monetary redistribution and deficit spending to push up wages artificially.
Similarly, an exit without further reforms could lead
to a repudiation of government debt. This would imply higher interest rates for
the government in the future (Eichengreen 2008, p. 10). An accompanying reform
of fiscal institutions such a constitutional limits for budget deficits could
alleviate this problem.
The End of Monetary Redistribution between Countries
Some countries benefit from the monetary setup of the
EMU. They pay lower interest rates on their debts than they otherwise would. If
a country like Greece exits the euro and repays its debts with a devalued new
currency, it will have to pay higher interest rates for its debts.
In addition, countries such as Greece could no longer
benefit from the monetary redistribution. The Greek government, and indirectly
part of the Greek population, benefits from the high Greek deficits and the
flow of new money into the country. This process allowed Greece to finance an
import surplus and standard of living it would not have achieved otherwise. At
least in the short term, an exit from the euro would, ceteris paribus, mean a
deterioration of artificially high living standards. In other words, after an
exit from the EMU, the size of its public sector and standard of living would
likely fall as the EMU subsidies end. These redistribution costs only apply to
countries that have been on the receiving end of the redistribution. For
fiscally sounder countries, the opposite reasoning applies.
Trade Losses
Some authors argue that European trade would collapse
in the wake of a euro exit. Trade barriers would be re-erected. In any case
there could be an appreciation of the new currency like a new deutschemark
(DM). In a UBS research paper, Flury and Wacker (2010, p. 3) estimate that the new
DM would appreciate about 25 percent.
In contrast to another UBS research paper (Deo,
Donovan and Hatheway 2011) that comes up with horrific costs of a euro break
up,[8] we do not regard such trade barriers as very
likely for several reasons. First, such barriers would be an economic disaster
for all involved parties and would lead to a severe and long depression and a
reduction of living standards. Second, net contributors to the EU, such as
Germany, could still use their contributions to the EU budget as a negotiating
card to prevent such barriers. Third, trade barriers are a blatant violation of
EU treaties. Fourth, tariffs could provoke severe tensions between nations,
possibly leading to war.
Political Costs
Sometimes it is maintained that an exit implies high
political costs. Most importantly, an exit could trigger the dissolution of the
euro.[9] The disintegration of the EMU could endanger the
development of a federal European state. At least, it would mean an important
blow to the "European project." It could mean the end of the EU as we
know today. The EU could "degenerate" into a free-trade zone.
Politicians of the exiting country would lose
influence on the policies of other EMU countries. The politicians of the
exiting country would also lose appreciation of other EMU politicians and in
the mainstream media that has supported the euro staunchly. However, for
supporters of a free-trade zone in Europe, these political costs imply immense
benefits. The danger of a federal European state would disappear for now.
Procedural Costs and Capital Flows
An exiting nation has to print new notes, mint new
coins, reprogram automatic teller machines, and rewrite computer code
(Eichengreen 2008, p. 17).[10] This takes time. The case of machines may not be
tragic, because, during the transition period, old machines may be in use
without chaos. A public parking place using euro coins will not bring the
economy down.
The notes-and-coins problem has a fast solution,
because on both the country's origin is visible. Coins have a country-specific
image and notes bear a country-specific letter. In a German exit from the euro,
all German coins and notes would be redenominated into the new currency and
later gradually exchanged into the new notes and coins.[11] Of course, the transition period would involve
some checking costs as people have to look at the symbols when transacting in
cash.
The most severe problem of a euro exit — one that
according to Eichengreen (2010) would pose "insurmountable" barriers
— is capital flows when the option of exiting is discussed.[12] Such a discussion takes time in democracies.
During this time there may be important capital inflows and outflows.[13]
Let us first discuss the problem of capital outflow
such as in the case of an exit of Greece with no accompanying reforms. If Greek
senior politicians seriously discuss an exit from the euro, Greek citizens will
expect a depreciation of the new currency, a new drachma. Greek citizens will
transfer their euros held at Greek banks to accounts in other EMU countries.
They will probably not turn in their euro notes to be exchanged for the new
drachmas voluntarily.
Greek citizens may also acquire other currencies such
as Swiss francs, US dollars, or gold to protect themselves from depreciation.
In this way Greece could practically be immunized against the new drachma even
before its introduction. As a consequence, the Greek banking system may get
into liquidity and solvency problems. Meanwhile, Greek citizens would continue
to transact in euros held outside Greek jurisdiction.
This is the so-called "problem" of capital
outflows. Yet these outflows are not a problem for ordinary Greek citizens. For
them these outflows are a solution to the problem of an inflationary national
currency. Moreover, capital outflows are already occurring. The discussion in
parliament of a Greek exit would only speed up what is happening already.
The opposite reasoning applies when a more solvent
country like Germany discusses an exit from the eurozone. If people expect an
appreciation of a newly introduced currency, there would be capital inflows
into Germany. The money supply of euros within Germany, which would later be
converted into a new currency, would increase. Prices of German assets (e.g.,
housing and stocks) would increase in advance of the actual German exit,
benefitting the current owners of such assets.
A Systemic Banking Crisis
Finally, there may be negative feedback for the
banking system as there will most likely be losses for banks both domestic and
foreign.[14],[15] Eichengreen (2010) fears the "mother of all
financial crises." Due to connectivity, it does not matter if Germany or
Greece leaves the euro. If Greece leaves the euro and pays back its government
bonds in a depreciated new currency or defaults outright, there will be losses
for European banks that could get into solvency problems. Similarly, if Germany
leaves the euro, the implicit guarantee and support to the Eurosystem will
disappear. The result may be a banking crisis in Greece and other countries.
The banking crisis might negatively affect German banks.[16] The banking crisis would also negatively affect
sovereigns, due to possible bank recapitalizations. Other countries may be
regarded as possible defaulters or exit candidates leading to higher interest
rates on public debts. A systemic financial crisis infecting weak governments
would be likely (Boone and Johnson 2011).
Recently, the IMF suggested that European banks face €300 billion
in potential losses and urged the banks to raise capital.[17] We should emphasize that the problem of bank
undercapitalization and bad assets (most importantly, peripheral government
bonds) does already exist in the EMU and will deteriorate without an exit.
It is almost impossible to leave the euro without
already-unstable structures collapsing. Yet this collapse would have the
beneficial effect of quickly purging unsustainable structures. Even if there
are no exits from the euro, the banking problem exists and will have to be
solved sooner or later. Potential bank insolvency should therefore be no
argument against an exit.[18] In the EMU taxpayers (mostly German) and
inflationary measures by the ECB are momentarily containing the situation. An
exit would speed up a restructuring of the European banking system.
At this point I would like to give the following
recommendation for a solution of the banking crisis. There are important
free-market solutions to bank-solvency problems.[19]
1. Banks with nonviable business models should be allowed
to fail, liberating capital and resources for other business projects.
3. Banks may collect private capital by issuing equity,
as they are already doing.
A free-market reform has important advantages:
1. Taxpayers are not
hurt.
2. Unsustainable banking projects are resolved. As the
banking sector is oversized, it would shrink to a more healthy and sustainable
level.
3. No inflationary policies are used to sustain the
banking system.
4. Moral hazard is avoided. Banks will not be bailed out.
The Problem of
Disentangling the European Central Bank
The Eurosystem consists of the ECB and national
central banks. The task of disentangling is facilitated because national
central banks still possess their own reserves and have their own balance
sheets. Scott (1998) argues that this setup may have been intentional.
Countries wanted to retain the possibility of leaving the euro if necessary.
On January 1, 1999, the ECB started with capital of €5
billion. In December 2010 the capital was increased from €5.76 billion to
€10.76 billion.[21]
Only part of all EMU reserve assets have been pooled
in the ECB, making a disentangling easier. On January 1, 1999, national central
banks provided €50 billion in reserve assets pro rata to their capital
contribution (Procter and Thieffrey 1998, p. 6). National central banks
retained the "ownership" of these foreign reserve assets and
transferred the management of the reserves to the ECB. (Scott 1998, p. 217). In
the case of an exit, both the return of the contribution to the ECB's capital
and the foreign assets transferred to the Eurosystem had to be negotiated
(Anthanassiou 2009).
Similarly, there is the problem of TARGET2 claims and
liabilities. If Germany had left the EMU in March 2012, the Bundesbank would
have found TARGET2 claims denominated in euros of more than €616 billion on its
balance sheet. If the euro depreciated against the new DM, important losses for
the Bundesbank would result.[22] As a consequence, the German government may have
to recapitalize the Bundesbank. Take into account, however, that these losses
would only acknowledge the risk and losses that the Bundesbank and the German
treasury are facing within the EMU. This risk is rising every day the
Bundesbank stays within the EMU.
If, in contrast, Greece leaves the EMU, it would be
less problematic for the departing country. Greece would simply pay its credits
to the ECB with the new drachmas, involving losses for the ECB. Depositors
would move their accounts from Greek banks to German banks leading to TARGET2
claims for the Bundesbank. As the credit risk of the Bundesbank would keep
increasing due to TARGET2 surpluses, the Bundesbank might well want to pull the
plug on the euro itself (Brookes 1998).[23]
Intellectual honesty requires us to admit that there
are important costs to exiting the euro, such as legal problems or the
disentangling of the ECB. However, these costs can be mitigated by reforms or
clever handling. Some of the alleged costs are actually benefits from the point
of liberty, such as political costs or liberating capital flows. Indeed, other
costs may be seen as an opportunity, such as a banking crisis that is used to
reform the financial system and finally put it on a sound basis. In any case,
these costs have to be compared with the enormous benefits of exiting the
system, consisting in the possible implosion of the Eurosystem. Exiting the
euro implies ending being part of an inflationary, self-destructing monetary
system with growing welfare states, falling competitiveness, bailouts,
subsidies, transfers, moral hazard, conflicts between nations, centralization,
and in general a loss of liberty.
Notes
[1] Reiermann
(2011) discusses rumors of a possible Greek exit. Desmond Lachman (2011)
maintains that Greece exit from the eurozone is inevitable. Feldstein (2010)
recommends that Greece take a "holiday" from the euro. Johnson (2011)
and Roubini (2011) recommend that Greece leave the euro and default. Alexandre
(2011) and Knowles (2011) wonder how a Greek exit could be achieved. Edmund
Conway (2011), on the contrary, thinks that Germany should leave the eurozone.
David Champion (2011) also considers the possibility of a German exit.
[2] Smits
(2005, p. 464) writes, "There is no legal way for a separate exit from the
eurozone. So, an intention to give up the single currency can only be realized
by negotiating an exit agreement, or, failing successful conclusion thereof,
leaving [the EU altogether] after the two-year notice period."
[3] Anthanassiou
(2009, p. 19), in contrast, argues that no country can leave the eurozone in
protest.
[4] Mann
(1960) maintains that if it is unclear which currency should be applied, the
courts should use the law specified in the contract. So if the bond of the
German company is sold in Paris under French law, the contract would be paid in
euros. Porter (2010, p. 4) reaches the same conclusion.
[5] Thieffry
(2011, p. 104) fears a "serious legal dislocation of government bond
markets and a long period of uncertainty." Problems for irresponsible
governments to finance deficit spending might actually be seen as advantageous.
[6] See Newsat
(2001).
[7] The
argument of increased competitiveness via depreciation has more fundamental
problems (Rallo 2011, p.158). While it is important to lower some prices
vis-Ã -vis the foreign world (e.g., wages in some sectors), depreciation lowers
all prices to the same extent. Moreover, it makes imports more expensive. If a
country has to import commodities and goods that are later exported, the
depreciation may not increase competitiveness at all.
[8] The
authors estimate the costs for "weak" countries to leave between
€9,500 and €11,500 per person and €6,000 to €8,000 per person for
"strong" countries. The authors contrast these numbers with the
relatively small cost of €1,000 per German in the case of a 50 percent haircut
on Greek government debt. These estimations neglect some important benefits of
exit and exaggerate the costs. For instance, they do not take into account the
long-term costs of a fiscal union, nor the higher inflation. Moreover, they
assume that the "strong" leaving country would have to "write
off its export industry" and civil disorder in weak countries, while the
possibility of such disorder it actually higher staying within the eurozone.
[9] On the
history of the political project of the euro as a means toward a central
European state see Bagus (2010).
[10] Flury and
Wacker (2010) estimate one year of transition to fully establish the new
currency.
[11] An
alternative solution would be to stamp all notes in the exiting country within
a short period of time. Yet, there is the problem of massive inflow of notes or
a population that does not bring in their notes to be stamped due to fear of
future depreciation. Thus, we regard the exchange of notes bearing the national
letter more practical, even though some of the notes are circulating in other
EMU countries.
[12] Smith
(2005, p. 465) points to the instability caused by speculations about an exit:
"even the threat of withdrawal will affect the euro stability and may lead
to speculation against the single currency." Scott (1998, p. 211) argues
that speculation on which country is to leave may lead to a breakup of the
eurozone.
[13] Porter
(2010, p.6 ) depicts the following scenario: If Germany is expected to
introduce a strong currency. banks will transfer deposits to Germany. They
could lend at the marginal lending rate of their central banks and deposit at
the Bundesbank. The Bundesbank balance sheet would expand substantially. Porter
suggests a surprise shut down of the TARGET2 system.
[14] Another
alleged problem is contagion. If one country leaves the eurozone, investors may
sell the debt of other weak EMU governments and their banks triggering more
exits. The contagion problem does not concern us here, because we want to
discuss the possibility of exit. If exit is possible and desirable, contagion
is no insurmountable problem but may even be recommendable.
[15] As Porter
(2010, p. 5) points out, an exit would result in a currency mismatch of many
companies and banks. Suddenly they would have assets or debts denominated in a
foreign currency with a changing value resulting in windfall profits or losses.
As Germany has a net foreign-asset position and an exit would likely lead to an
appreciation of the new German currency, losses would result. The losses would
damage balance sheets.
[16] Flury and
Wacker (2010) discuss this and other problems related to a German exit from the
euro.
[17] See Reddy
(2011).
[18] One may
also ask whether a country should have rejected the possibility of secession
from the Soviet Union in fear of banking problems.
[19] For a
detailed plan and critique of the 2008 bailouts, see Bagus and Rallo (2011).
[20] Ideally,
this conversion would be voluntary. If bank creditors are unwilling to convert
their investments into equity, the bank would have to be liquidated with high
losses due to fire sales. Thus, there is an incentive for creditors to convert
bank debts into equity, if the business model is be viable. Doing so they can
prevent the higher losses from a liquidation. On the contrary, Buiter (2008)
has suggested an involuntary, across-the-board debt-equity conversion. This
measure is unnecessary if we allow for bank failures.
[21] The
Bundesbank capital share is 27.1 percent. The paid up capital is €1.4 billion.
(The Bundesbank's capital share is 18.93 percent including both eurozone and
noneurozone members.)
[22] A
depreciation of the euro implies a loss of almost €100 billion.
[23] Note that
the claims or liabilities in the TARGET2 system are not against other national
central banks, but a single net bilateral position is established vis-á-vis the
ECB only (Whittaker 2011). See also Bundesbank (2011b, p. 34).
References
Arghyrou, Michael G. and John D. Tsoukalas. 2010.
"The Option Of Last Resort: A Two-Currency Emu." Cardiff Economics Working Papers. E2010/14
Athanassiou, Phoebus. 2009. "Withdrawal and
expulsion from the EU and EMU — Some Reflections." ECB Legal Working Paper Series. No. 10 December.
Alexandre, Carlos. 2011. "Mission Impossible: how
can Greece exit the euro." Seekingalpha. June
28th.
http://seekingalpha.com/article/276915-mission-impossible-how-can-greece-exit-the-euro
http://seekingalpha.com/article/276915-mission-impossible-how-can-greece-exit-the-euro
Bagus, Philipp. 2008. "Monetary Reform and
Deflation — A Critique of Mises, Rothbard, Huerta de Soto and Sennholz." New Perspectives on Political Economy, 4 (2) :
131–157.
Bagus, Philipp. 2009a. "The Quality of
Money." Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 12
(4): pp. 41–64.
Bagus, Philipp. 2009b. "Monetary Reform — The
Case for Button-Pushing." New Perspectives on Political
Economy, 5 (2) 2009, 111–128.
Bagus, Philipp. 2010. The
Tragedy of the Euro. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Bagus, Philipp and Juan Ramón Rallo. 2011. "A
free-market bailout." Universidad Rey Juan Carlos
Working Paper.
Boone, Peter and Simon Johnson. 2011. "Europe on
the brink." Policy Brief, July. Peterson Institute
for International Economics.
Brookes, Martin. 1998. "Could Speculation Break
EMU Apart?" European Economic Analyst. 98/1,
January 8th.
Buiter, Willem (2008), "More and Different:
Including a Debt-Equity Swap for the Financial Sector,"
www.ft.com/maverecon. (21 September)
www.ft.com/maverecon. (21 September)
Bundesbank. 2011a. "Monthly Report". August
2011. Available at:
http://www.bundesbank.de/download/volkswirtschaft/monatsberichte/2011/201108mb_en.pdf
Bundesbank. 2011b. "Monthly Report". March
2011. Available at:
http://www.bundesbank.de/download/volkswirtschaft/monatsberichte/2011/201103mb_en.pdf
Champion, David. 2011. "Will Germany leave the
Euro?" Harvard Business Review Blog. July
1st.
http://blogs.hbr.org/hbr/hbreditors/2011/07/will_germany_leave_the_euro.html
http://blogs.hbr.org/hbr/hbreditors/2011/07/will_germany_leave_the_euro.html
Conway, Edmund. 2011. "Why Germany must exit the
Euro." The Telegraph. June 18th.http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/financialcrisis/8584064/Why-Germany-must-exit-the-euro.html
Cotterill, Joseph. 2011. "Euro exit as legal
quagmire." May 12th.http://ftalphaville.ft.com/blog/2011/05/12/566031/euro-exit-as-legal-quagmire/
Deo, Stephane, Paul Donovan and Larry Hatheway. 2011.
"Euro break-up — the consequences." UBS Investment Research.
Global Economic Perspectives. September 6.
Eichengreen, Barry. 2008. "The Breakup of the
Euro Area". Working Paper. University of California. October.
Eichengreen, Barry. 2010. "The euro: Love it or
leave it." Vox. May 4th. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729
Feldstein, Martin. 2010. "Let Greece take a
Eurozone 'holiday'." Financial Times.
February 16th.
http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/72214942–1b30–11df-953f-00144feab49a.html#axzz1Y8h6SSbK
http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/72214942–1b30–11df-953f-00144feab49a.html#axzz1Y8h6SSbK
Fidrmuc, Jan and Július Horváth. 1998. "
Stability of Monetary Unions: Lessons from the Break-up of
Czechoslovakia". Transition Economics Series No.10.
Institut für höhere Studien Wien.
Flury, Thomas and Thomas Wacker. 2010. "If
Germany were to leave the Euro." UBS Research Focus.
December 24th.
Hayek, F. A. von (1990), Denationalisation of Money —
The Argument Refined. An Analysis of the Theory and Practice of Concurrent
Currencies, 3rd ed. London: Economic Affairs.
Hoppe, Hans Hermann. 1993. "Nationalism and
Secession." Chronicles. November, pp. 23–25.
Huerta de Soto, Jesús. 2009. Money, Bank Credit and Economic Cycles. 2nd Ed. Auburn,
Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Johnson, Boris. 2011. "The greatest gift to the
Greeks might be let them go it alone." Telegraph.co June
11.http://www.telegraph.co.uk/comment/columnists/borisjohnson/8585734/The-greatest-gift-to-the-Greeks-might-be-to-let-them-go-it-alone.html
Karlsson, Stefan. 2010. "Right and wrong from
Eichengreen about euro area breakup." Csmonitor.com February
18th.
http://www.csmonitor.com/Business/Stefan-Karlsson-s-Blog/2010/0218/Right-and-wrong-from-Eichengreen-about-euro-area-breakup
http://www.csmonitor.com/Business/Stefan-Karlsson-s-Blog/2010/0218/Right-and-wrong-from-Eichengreen-about-euro-area-breakup
Klaus, Václav. 2006. "The Economic Transformation
of the Czech Republic: Challenges faces and lessons learned."Economic Development Bulletin. Cato Institute.No. 6.
February 14.
Klein, B. (1974), "The Competitive Supply of
Money", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 6 (4): 423–53.
Knowles, Daniel. 2011. "Can Greece actually leave
the Euro." Telegraph. June 20th.http://blogs.telegraph.co.uk/news/danielknowles/100092965/can-greece-actually-leave-the-euro/
Lachman, Desmond. 2011. "A Tale of a Euro exit
foretold." The American. July 5th.http://www.american.com/archive/2011/july/a-tale-of-a-euro-exit-foretold
Larouchepac. 2010. "Germany could exit Euro
'overnight'." May 25th. http://www.larouchepac.com/node/14591
Mann, F.A. 1960. Money in International Public
Law, Leyden: Hague Academy of International Law.
Newsat. 2001." Spezial: Der Euro." www.news.at May 30th. Available at:http://www.news.at/articles/0122/30/15083/spezial-der-euro
Porter, William. 2010. "'Leaving the EMU 'is just
an expensive way to default." Credit Suisse Fixed Income
Research. March 15th
Procter, Charles and Gilles Thieffrey. 1998.
"Economic and Monetary Union. Thinking the unthinkable — the break-up of
the economic and monetary union." Norton Rose.
Available at: http://gtlaw.ch/publications/Economic_and_;pmetary_Union.pdf
Rallo, Juan Ramón. 2011. Crónicas de la gran recession (2007–2009). Madrid:
Unión Editorial.
Reddy, Sudeep. 2011. "IMF urges EU bank to raise
capital." Wallstreet Online. September 22th.
Available at:http://online.wsj.com/article/SB20001424053111903791504576584601528811970.html
Reiermann, Christian. 2011. "Greece considers
exit form Euro zone." Spiegel.online. June
5th 2011.
http://www.spiegel.de/international/europe/0,1518,761201,00.html
http://www.spiegel.de/international/europe/0,1518,761201,00.html
Roubini, Nouriel. 2011. "Greece should default
and abandon the Euro." Economonitor.
September 22.
http://www.economonitor.com/nouriel/2011/09/22/full-analysis-greece-should-default-and-abandon-the-euro/?utm_source=rss&utm_medium=rss&utm_campaign=full-analysis-greece-should-default-and-abandon-the-euro&utm_medium=twitter&utm_source=twitterfeed
http://www.economonitor.com/nouriel/2011/09/22/full-analysis-greece-should-default-and-abandon-the-euro/?utm_source=rss&utm_medium=rss&utm_campaign=full-analysis-greece-should-default-and-abandon-the-euro&utm_medium=twitter&utm_source=twitterfeed
Ruparel, Raoul, and Mats Persson. 2011. "A House
Built on Sand? The ECB and the hidden cost of saving the Euro."OpenEurope. Updated version. June. Available at:
http://www.openeurope.org.uk/research/ecbandtheeuro.pdf
Scott, Hal S. 1998. "When the Euro falls
apart." International Finance 12,
207–228.
Sinn, Hans-Werner and Timo Wollmershäuser. 2011.
"Target Loans, Current Account Balances and Capital Flows: The ECB's
Rescue Facility." CESifo Working Paper 3500. Available at www.cesifo.org/wp
Sinn, Hans-Werner. 2011. "Die Rettungssummen
steigen" ifo Schnelldienst 17/2011, p.
22. http://www.cesifo-group.de/link/ifosd_2011_17_sinn.pdf
Smits, René. 2005. "The European Constitution and
EMU: An Appraisal." Common Market Law Review 42:
425–68..
SpiegelOnline. 2011. "Bundesbank-Chef warnt vor
Milliarden-Risiken." Stk/Reuters. 17.09.
2011
http://www.spiegel.de/wirtschaft/soziales/0,1518,786847,00.html
http://www.spiegel.de/wirtschaft/soziales/0,1518,786847,00.html
Thieffry, Gilles. 2011. "Thinking of the
probable: The Break-up of Monetary Union." Journal
of International Banking Law and Regulation, no. 3, pp. 103–04.
Vaubel, R. (1977), "Free Currency
Competition", Review of World Economics, 113 (3): 435–61.
Whittaker, John. 2011. "Intra-eurosystem
debts."Working paper. Lancaster University Management School.
Zerohedge. 2011. "The fatal flaw in Europe's
second "bazooka" bailout: 82 million soon to be very angry Germans.
Or how Euro bailout #2 could cost up to 56 percent of German GDP." Zerohedge.com Tyler Durden. 21th July. Available
at: http://www.zerohedge.com/article/fatal-flaw-europes-second-bazooka-bailout-82-million-soon-be-very-angry-germans
No comments:
Post a Comment