Poverty remains a story of bad decision-making and out-of-wedlock child-rearing.
BY HEATHER MAC DONALD
Desperate single mothers are
mugging illegal aliens, shoplifting, and fencing stolen goods in order to
survive, and it’s all the fault of those heartless Republicans and spineless
Democrats who passed the 1996 welfare reform law. Such, at least, is the message
of a front-page article in the New York
Times, the first salvo in a likely campaign to roll back the most
successful federal law in recent memory.
Temporary Assistance to Needy
Families (TANF) limited federal welfare payments to five years and conditioned
them on a recipient’s effort to find work—in essence, stripping welfare of its
entitlement status. As a result, the welfare rolls dropped two-thirds from 1996
to 2009, work rates of never-married mothers surged, and black child poverty
fell to its lowest level ever.
But according to Times reporter Jason DeParle, TANF has not performed as it should have during the recession. Rather than skyrocketing, the welfare rolls have risen “only” 15 percent since 2007, and still remain 68 percent below their pre-reform peak. Some people, of course, would see the relative stability in welfare usage as a sign of success—proof that TANF has permanently discouraged at least one form of dependency. Not DeParle, however, who tries to show that the law has resulted in severe hardship for single mothers at the bottom of the economic ladder, forcing them to turn to crime and other forms of hustling to survive.
To his credit, DeParle himself
provides much of the evidence that refutes his main story line. Nevertheless,
his piece reveals a continuing divide over the analysis of poverty and the
behavior that creates it, one that will grow more pointed in the coming years.
To set up the anti-TANF
argument, DeParle resurrects Georgetown law professor Peter Edelman, last seen
quitting his White House post in protest when President Bill Clinton signed
TANF. Edelman now claims vindication for his apocalyptic predictions regarding
welfare reform: “My take on it was the states would push people off and not let
them back on, and that’s just what they did,” he tells DeParle. “It’s been even
worse than I thought it would be.”
Edelman may well have been
right, DeParle suggests: some states have shortened their TANF time limits and
tightened eligibility requirements since the recession began, and in 16 states,
the rolls have shrunk over the last four years. (That still leaves 34 states,
of course, where the rolls have increased.) The implication is that any changes
in the welfare rules were unfair and made it impossible to alleviate legitimate
need, even though the states that have lowered their welfare rolls are spending
their federal TANF dollars on adoption, foster care, and other programs of
arguably greater importance to child welfare than monthly welfare checks.
DeParle notes that some states “explicitly” pursue a policy of deterrence to
make sure that people use the program only as a last resort (horrors!) and incredulously
quotes Michigan’s welfare director explaining his state’s caseload drop: “We
[still] have a fair number of people gaming the system.” The possibility that
this administrator may be right is never considered.
DeParle introduces us to some
of the alleged victims of TANF, all from Arizona: a woman who “rob[s]
wetbacks,” in her words, and lures other men into traps where accomplices also
rob them; a 21-year-old mother of two who went to a shelter after her welfare
checks stopped, then returned to a boyfriend with a violent temper; a
29-year-old mother of four who helps a friend sell shoplifted clothes; and, in
a classic Times stroke, an illegal immigrant who ran out the
time limits on her four children’s welfare checks and now scavenges for cans and
bottles en famille.
We are presumably to assume
that these women have tried diligently but unsuccessfully to find work, though
DeParle never says so explicitly. In fact, only 12 percent of the nonworking
poor surveyed in 2009 by New York University professor Larry Mead said that
they weren’t working because they couldn’t find a job. We are most certainly supposed
to assume that a 21-year-old mother of two should not have been expected to
assess whether she and her male sexual partners were ready to support a family;
it is for her to have babies and for taxpayers to provide for them. And if TANF
cuts off that support for failure to comply with its rules, the problem lies
with the law, not with the decision-making that led to the need for welfare in
the first place.
DeParle implies without much
proof that such alleged hardship cases have been increasing. He cites a study
showing that about 1.5 million low-income single mothers are jobless and
without cash aid—twice the rate as before TANF. The percentage of female-headed
households in “deep poverty” (defined as half the official poverty-level
income) is at its highest level in 18 years, according to the Census Bureau
(yet still less than the pre-TANF peak). Another study finds that one of every
50 children comes from a household living on less than $2 a day per person.
But as DeParle himself
recognizes, the claim that welfare reform has exacerbated economic hardship is
contradicted by other data. Despite the recession, the poverty rate of single
mothers remains lower than it was before welfare reform. In New York City, the
percentage of never-married, female-headed households in “deep poverty” in 2010
was almost 30 percent below the peak in 1995. Self-reported consumption levels
of poor single mothers have improved since welfare reform passed, confirming
the view of many analysts that traditional poverty measures significantly
underreport income. Nearly 60 percent of the families whom DeParle portrays as
the main victims of welfare reform—those neither working nor receiving cash
aid—change their status within the year, in part because entry-level jobs have
remained available in many places, including New York City, during the
recession. (Whether welfare recipients have the self-discipline to keep those
jobs is another matter.)
And, as DeParle concedes, the
poor “can turn to other programs like food stamps and Medicaid” to supplement
their welfare check. Can turn? Theyhave been
turning to food stamps in droves, now that the Obama administration has
loosened eligibility requirements and campaigned to sign up as many people as
possible. Tellingly, food stamps ask nothing of the recipient and have no time
limits, and poverty advocates have all but eliminated the last remaining checks
on food stamp fraud. It’s no surprise, then, that in 2010, the federal
government spent twice as much on food stamps as it did in 2007, as economist
and New York Times blogger Casey Mulligan reports.
Other forms of assistance have
also shot through the roof; in fact, more taxpayer money sloshes around the
bottom of the income ladder than ever before. In Detroit, one in five adults
are now on SSI, the disability program for the never-working poor, though it’s
unlikely that one in five adults in Detroit are actually unable to work. As
DeParle notes, one-quarter of poor single mothers pay rents as low as $50 a
month, thanks to taxpayer-subsidized housing. Even the illegal alien whom
DeParle celebrates for collecting recyclables, rather than stealing, lives in
subsidized housing and cashes in $650 a month in food stamps—this in allegedly
immigrant-hostile Arizona. (The father of her children lives in subsidized
housing as well: he is in prison.)
Indeed, the growth in non-TANF
welfare programs suggests a less rosy interpretation of the relatively flat
TANF usage since the recession began: it’s not that potential recipients have
absorbed a strengthened norm against dependency, but that they have migrated to undemanding forms of welfare.
But if the empirical case for
TANF’s harmful effects is weak, the philosophical case against it lacks any
merit at all. DeParle implies that the most disorganized, incompetent single
mothers would be better off with more unconditional government money coming in
every month. Jason Turner, the visionary architect of welfare reform in New
York and Wisconsin, suggests a thought experiment to test that view: increase
the government cash coming in to the most disorderly households by 50 percent,
he says. Would these never-working mothers get jobs? Would they marry? Would
they stop taking drugs, save for the future, or teach their children the
importance of self-discipline and honesty? The answer to all these questions,
Turner rightly concludes, is no. None of the most important determinants of
success for adults and children would change for the better in these
welfare-supported households. Instead the mothers would most likely spend their
additional cash on the items they already consume—entertainment, clothes,
electronics, and food and restaurants.
Moreover, reopening the spigot
of unconditional cash could jeopardize a more vital segment of society, Turner
argues—the still-working poor. Welfare reform sought to send the message that
work is the primary route to income in all but the most extreme cases of
disability. Once welfare becomes an alternative to work, and the rewards for
non-work increase, the working poor might decide to join the dependency class.
Conservatives can argue for
the value of welfare reform until they’re blue in the face, however, but they
can always be trumped, at least in venues like the New York Times,
by the inevitable parade of single mothers barely scraping by. Indeed,
conservatives left themselves open to being so trumped by stressing the “You
go, girl!” aspects of welfare reform. They rightly cheered on the newly engaged
welfare mother but wrongly implied that single-parent households could be made
whole if the mothers would just go to work. It remains the case, however, that
with or without welfare reform, the lot of most never-married mothers and their
children is miserable. As DeParle notes, the well-being of fatherless
children—measured by grades, crime, drug use, and life aspirations—did not
significantly improve after their mothers went to work.
It is time, therefore, to
tackle the problem of out-of-wedlock births head-on. And that means
remoralizing the discourse around child-bearing. When DeParle profiles a
21-year-old mother of two as a victim of welfare reform because she is
allegedly forced to live with an ill-tempered boyfriend now that her welfare payments
have run out, conservatives can legitimately ask what has become a taboo
question: “Why didn’t you think of that before you had the children?” So
assiduously nonjudgmental is the liberal discourse around poverty that DeParle
portrays the crime committed by single mothers as the consequence of welfare
reform—rather than of those mothers’ previous abysmal decision-making
regarding procreation and their present lack of morals. It’s unfair, he
implies, that single mothers have to double up with family members or return to
violent relationships. And of course, he stays silent about the men who
fathered the children of the mothers he profiles. Where are they? Who are they?
His article offers not a clue. They may as well not even exist, so little are
they expected to support their children. The only father we know about for sure
is the illegal-alien convict; the other shadowy boyfriends, passingly mentioned
only as inappropriate roommates, may or may not be the fathers of their current
girlfriends’ children.
The Left’s essential strategy
when it comes to poverty is to assess need and desert only in the present
moment. If someone shows up at a welfare office saying: “I have no means of
support for myself and my children,” the proper role of the government bureaucrat
is to ask: “How big a check do you require?” rather than: “What did you do to
put yourself into this situation?”
Conservatives should respond
to the Left’s present-oriented framework for analyzing welfare and poverty by
reintroducing the connection between past behavior and present need. Underclass
poverty doesn’t just happen to people, as the Left implies. It is almost always
the consequence of poor decision-making—above all, having children out of
wedlock. A single mother almost inevitably faces a life of stress and
instability, even if she gets a job per TANF rules. More importantly,
out-of-wedlock child-rearing is profoundly irresponsible. The evidence is
incontrovertible: children raised in single-parent homes do worse on all
measures of socialization than those raised by married parents.
Over the last decade and a
half, the Right has gotten sucked up into an increasingly sterile debate about
the nuts and bolts of welfare reform: whether to impose full-check or
partial-check sanctions for rule violations, for example, or what the proper
size of the caseload-reduction credit should be. Such a focus on regulatory
minutiae was necessary in the early stages of welfare reform, since turning
around welfare bureaucracies from check-writing structures to work-incentivizing
organizations was essential to TANF’s success. But by now it’s clear that
requiring welfare mothers to work or any other possible tweaks to the rules is
not going to change underclass norms around child-rearing, as TANF’s drafters
had wistfully hoped. And the seeming intractability of out-of-wedlock
child-rearing guarantees future demand for big-government programs. What is
needed now is a full-throated campaign in every government office, bully
pulpit, and private agency to reassert the value of fatherhood and marriage.
No comments:
Post a Comment