by Ludwig von Mises
Knowledge of the effects of government interference
with market prices makes us comprehend the economic causes of a momentous
historical event, the decline of ancient civilization.
It may be left undecided whether or not it is correct
to call the economic organization of the Roman Empire capitalism. At any rate
it is certain that the Roman Empire in the 2nd century, the age of the
Antonines, the "good" emperors, had reached a high stage of the
social division of labor and of interregional commerce. Several metropolitan
centers, a considerable number of middle-sized towns, and many small towns were
the seats of a refined civilization.
The inhabitants of these urban agglomerations were supplied with food and raw materials not only from the neighboring rural districts, but also from distant provinces. A part of these provisions flowed into the cities as revenue of their wealthy residents who owned landed property. But a considerable part was bought in exchange for the rural population's purchases of the products of the city dwellers' processing activities.
The inhabitants of these urban agglomerations were supplied with food and raw materials not only from the neighboring rural districts, but also from distant provinces. A part of these provisions flowed into the cities as revenue of their wealthy residents who owned landed property. But a considerable part was bought in exchange for the rural population's purchases of the products of the city dwellers' processing activities.
There was an extensive trade between the various
regions of the vast empire. Not only in the processing industries, but also in
agriculture there was a tendency toward further specialization. The various
parts of the empire were no longer economically self-sufficient. They were
interdependent.
What brought about the decline of the empire and the
decay of its civilization was the disintegration of this economic
interconnectedness, not the barbarian invasions. The alien aggressors merely
took advantage of an opportunity which the internal weakness of the empire
offered to them. From a military point of view the tribes which invaded the
empire in the 4th and 5th centuries were not more formidable than the armies which
the legions had easily defeated in earlier times. But the empire had changed.
Its economic and social structure was already medieval.
The freedom that Rome granted to commerce and trade
had always been restricted. With regard to the marketing of cereals and other
vital necessities it was even more restricted than with regard to other
commodities. It was deemed unfair and immoral to ask for grain, oil, and wine,
the staples of these ages, more than the customary prices, and the municipal
authorities were quick to check what they considered profiteering. Thus the
evolution of an efficient wholesale trade in these commodities was prevented.
The policy of the annona, which was
tantamount to a nationalization or municipalization of the grain trade, aimed
at filling the gaps. But its effects were rather unsatisfactory. Grain was
scarce in the urban agglomerations, and the agriculturists complained about the
unremunerativeness of grain growing.
The interference of the authorities upset the
adjustment of supply to the rising demand.
The showdown came when in the political troubles of
the 3rd and 4th centuries the emperors resorted to currency debasement. With
the system of maximum prices, the practice of debasement completely paralyzed
both the production and the marketing of the vital foodstuffs and disintegrated
society's economic organization. The more eagerness the authorities displayed
in enforcing the maximum prices, the more desperate became the conditions of
the urban masses dependent on the purchase of food.
Commerce in grain and other necessities vanished
altogether.
To avoid starving, people deserted the cities, settled
on the countryside, and tried to grow grain, oil, wine, and other necessities
for themselves. On the other hand, the owners of the big estates restricted
their excess production of cereals and began to produce in their farmhouses —
the villae— the products of handicraft which they needed.
For their big-scale farming, which was already seriously jeopardized because of
the inefficiency of slave labor, lost its rationality completely when the
opportunity to sell at remunerative prices disappeared.
As the owner of the estate could no longer sell in the
cities, he could no longer patronize the urban artisans either. He was forced
to look for a substitute to meet his needs by employing handicraftsmen on his
own account in his villa. He
discontinued big-scale farming and became a landlord receiving rents from
tenants or sharecroppers. These coloni were
either freed slaves or urban proletarians who settled in the villages and
turned to tilling the soil.
A tendency toward the establishment of autarky of each
landlord's estate emerged. The economic function of the cities, of commerce,
trade, and urban handicrafts, shrank. Italy and the provinces of the empire
returned to a less advanced state of the social division of labor. The highly
developed economic structure of ancient civilization retrograded to what is now
known as the manorial organization of the Middle Ages.
The emperors were alarmed with that outcome, which
undermined the financial and military power of their government. But their
counteraction was futile as it did not affect the root of the evil. The
compulsion and coercion to which they resorted could not reverse the trend
toward social disintegration which, on the contrary, was caused precisely by
too much compulsion and coercion.
No Roman was aware of the fact that the process was
induced by the government's interference with prices and by currency
debasement. It was vain for the emperors to promulgate laws against the city
dweller who "relicta civitate rus habitare maluerit."[2]
The system of the leiturgia, the
public services to be rendered by the wealthy citizens, only accelerated the
retrogression of the division of labor. The laws concerning the special
obligations of the shipowners, the navicularii, were no
more successful in checking the decline of navigation than the laws concerning
grain dealing in checking the shrinkage in the cities' supply of agricultural
products.
The marvelous civilization of antiquity perished
because it did not adjust its moral code and its legal system to the
requirements of the market economy. A social order is doomed if the actions
which its normal functioning requires are rejected by the standards of
morality, are declared illegal by the laws of the country, and are prosecuted
as criminal by the courts and the police.
The Roman Empire crumbled to dust because it lacked
the spirit of liberalism and free enterprise. The policy of interventionism and
its political corollary, the Führer principle, decomposed the mighty empire as
they will by necessity always disintegrate and destroy any social entity.
No comments:
Post a Comment