Today, the Latvian
government can claim victory. In the first quarter of this year, Latvia’s
annualized GDP grew by 6.8 percent, the highest growth rate in Europe, and last
year Latvia recorded a growth rate of 5.5 percent, the third highest in Europe.
Four years ago, GDP plummeted by a total of 24 percent because of the sudden
stop of international financing in September 2008. But that decline lasted only
two years. Unemployment has fallen from 21 percent in early 2010 to 16 percent
two years later.
How times can change. In December 2008, Paul Krugman
claimed, “Latvia is the new Argentina.” In June 2009, Nouriel Roubini asserted
that “devaluation seems unavoidable” and that the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) and the European Union were “throwing good money after bad” in their
support of Latvia’s stabilization program.
But Latvia did not devalue. Instead it carried out a
vigorous “internal devaluation,” with large cuts in public expenditures and
wages as well as structural reforms, while supported financially by the IMF and
the European Union. Many argue that Latvia is special, but the Latvian
government did exactly what it was supposed to do and the Latvian people
understand that. Remarkably, Valdis Dombrovskis, who became prime minister in
the midst of the crisis in March 2009 and led the cure, has been reelected
twice in parliamentary elections since then.
Latvia’s crisis resolution is a political economy success story. The only strange feature is that, to the surprise of people who should have known better, everybody in Latvia did more or less what they were supposed to do and they did so in time. The government managed to carry out its policy in a cohesive fashion and restored both domestic and international confidence at an early stage. Latvia’s achievement boils down to five crucial principles, which the South Europeans have ignored—and continue to ignore—at their peril.
First and perhaps most important, Latvia used the
grave sense of crisis in the fall of 2008 to take action. When a country is in
a serious crisis, any delay of crisis resolution is harmful.
Second, the government composed swiftly a
comprehensive anti-crisis program, which was heavily front-loaded and thus
restored confidence early on.
Third, the program contained more expenditure cuts
than revenue increase measures, which helped restore confidence early and drove
structural reforms, and which are likely to promote economic growth. The crisis
forced Latvia to trim its public sector, rendering its already efficient
economic system even more competitive. The front-loaded Latvian anti-crisis
programs encountered minimal social resistance. The Latvian government proved
that radical spending cuts and structural reforms are perfectly possible in
well-functioning democracies.
Fourth, the IMF and the European Union provided early
and sufficient international financial support, making the crisis resolution
financially sustainable.
Finally, the government managed to sell its adjustment
program to the electorate, by clarifying how severe the crisis was and by
making sure that more of the burden of the crisis was borne by those who were
better off.
The governments in Southern Europe could have followed
in Latvia’s footsteps, but they chose not to. They have satisfied none of these
five crucial conditions. It is true that their public debt burden is far
larger, but proportionately they have been offered far greater financing than
Latvia, while they have done far less. Their actions have not been commensurate
with their conditions. It is time to realize that the question is not whether
the Latvian lessons are relevant to Southern Europe, but when the Southern
European governments will face up to reality.
No comments:
Post a Comment