by Robert Higgs
As the recession
has deepened and the financial debacle has passed from one flare-up to another
during the past seven or eight months, commentary on the economy’s troubles has
swelled tremendously. Pundits have pontificated; journalists and editors have
reported and opined; talk-radio jocks have huffed and puffed; public officials
have spewed out even more double-talk than usual; awkward academic experts,
caught in the camera’s glare like deer in the headlights, have blinked and
stumbled through their brief stints as talking heads on TV. We’ve been deluged
by an enormous outpouring of diagnosis, prognosis, and prescription, at least
ninety-five percent of which has been appallingly bad.
The bulk of it has been bad for the same reasons. Most of the people who purport to possess expertise about the economy rely on a common set of presuppositions and modes of thinking. I call this pseudo-intellectual mishmash vulgar Keynesianism. It’s the same claptrap that has passed for economic wisdom in this country for more than fifty years and seems to have originated in the first edition of Paul Samuelson’s Economics (1948), the best-selling economics textbook of all time and the one from which a plurality of several generations of college students acquired whatever they knew about economic analysis. Long ago, this view seeped into educated discourse and writing in the news media and in politics and established itself as an orthodoxy.
Unfortunately, this way of thinking about the economy’s operation, particularly its overall fluctuations, is a tissue of errors of both commission and omission. Most unfortunate have been the policy implications derived from this mode of thinking, above all the notion that the government can and should use fiscal and monetary policies to control the macroeconomy and stabilize its fluctuations. Despite having originated more than half a century ago, this view seems to be as vital in 2009 as it was in 1949.
Let us consider
briefly the six most egregious aspects of this unfortunate approach to
understanding and dealing with economic booms and busts.
Aggregation
John Maynard Keynes persuaded his fellow economists and then they persuaded the public that it makes sense to think of the economy in terms of a handful of economy-wide aggregates: total income or output, total consumption spending, total investment spending, and total net exports. If people remember anything from their introductory economics course, they are most likely to remember the equation:
John Maynard Keynes persuaded his fellow economists and then they persuaded the public that it makes sense to think of the economy in terms of a handful of economy-wide aggregates: total income or output, total consumption spending, total investment spending, and total net exports. If people remember anything from their introductory economics course, they are most likely to remember the equation:
Y = C + I + G + (X—M).
Sometimes Q • P is
equated to the variables on the right-hand side of the equation. So, the idea
is that aggregate supply (physical output times the price level) equals
aggregate demand equals the sum of four types of money expenditure for newly
produced final goods and services.
This way of
compressing diverse, economy-wide transactions into single variables has the
effect of suppressing recognition of the complex relationships and differences within each of the aggregates. Thus, in this
framework, the effect of adding a million dollars of investment spending for
teddy-bear inventories is the same as the effect of adding a million dollars of
investment spending for digging a new copper mine. Likewise, the effect of
adding a million dollars of consumption spending for movie tickets is the same
as the effect of adding a million dollars of consumption spending for gasoline.
Likewise, the effect of adding a million dollars of government spending for
children’s inoculations against polio is the same as the effect of adding a
million dollars of government spending for 7.62 mm ammunition. It does not take
much thought to conceive of ways in which suppression of the differences within
each of the aggregates might cause our thinking about the economy to go
seriously awry.
In fact, “the
economy” does not produce an undifferentiated mass we call “output.” Instead,
the millions of producers who bring forth “aggregate supply” provide an almost
infinite variety of specific goods and services that differ in countless ways.
Moreover, an immense amount of what goes on in a market economy consists of
dealings among producers who supply no “final” goods and services at all, but
instead supply raw materials, components, intermediate products, and services
to one another. Because these producers are connected in an intricate pattern
of relations, which must assume certain proportions if the entire arrangement
is to work effectively, critical consequences turn on what in particular gets produced, when, where, and how.
These
extraordinarily complex micro-relationships are what we are really referring to
when we speak of “the economy.” It is definitely not a single, simple process
for producing a uniform, aggregate glop. Moreover, when we speak of “economic
action,” we are referring to the choices that millions of diverse participants
make in selecting one course of action and setting aside a possible alternative.
Without choice, constrained by scarcity, no true economic action takes place.
Thus, vulgar Keynesianism, which purports to be an economic model or at least a
coherent framework of economic analysis, actually excludes the very possibility
of genuine economic action, substituting for it a simple, mechanical
conception, the intellectual equivalent of a baby toy.
Relative prices
Vulgar Keynesianism takes no account of relative prices or changes in such prices. After all, in this framework, there’s only one price, which is called “the price level” and represents a weighted average of all the money prices at which the economy’s countless actual goods and services are sold. (There’s also the rate of interest, which is treated as a price in a limited and misleading way; about which I say more later.) If relative prices change, which of course they always do to some extent, even in the most stable periods, these changes are “averaged out” and affect the calculated change, if any, in the aggregate price level only in a shrouded and analytically irrelevant manner.
Vulgar Keynesianism takes no account of relative prices or changes in such prices. After all, in this framework, there’s only one price, which is called “the price level” and represents a weighted average of all the money prices at which the economy’s countless actual goods and services are sold. (There’s also the rate of interest, which is treated as a price in a limited and misleading way; about which I say more later.) If relative prices change, which of course they always do to some extent, even in the most stable periods, these changes are “averaged out” and affect the calculated change, if any, in the aggregate price level only in a shrouded and analytically irrelevant manner.
So, if the economy
expands along certain lines, but not along others, in response to a change in
the configuration of relative prices, the vulgar Keynesians know that
“aggregate demand” and “aggregate supply” have risen, but they have no idea why
or in what manner they have risen. Nor do they care. In their view, the
economy’s aggregate output, the only output they treat as worthy of notice, is
driven by aggregate demand, to which aggregate supply responds more or less
automatically, and it matters not whether only the demand for cucumbers has
risen or, to cite an example Keynes himself used, only the demand for pyramids
has risen. Aggregate demand is aggregate demand is aggregate demand.
Because the vulgar
Keynesian has no conception of the economy’s structure of output, he cannot conceive of how an expansion
of demand along certain lines but not along others might be problematic. In his
view, one cannot have, say, too many houses and apartments. Increasing the
spending for houses and apartments is, he thinks, always good whenever the
economy has unemployed resources, regardless of how many houses and apartments
now stand vacant and regardless of what specific kinds of resources are
unemployed and where they are located in this vast land. Although the
unemployed laborers may be skilled silver miners in Idaho, it is supposedly
still a good thing if somehow the demand for condos is increased in Palm Beach,
because for the vulgar Keynesian, there are no individual classes of laborers
or separate labor markets: labor is labor is labor. If someone, whatever his
skills, preferences, or location, is unemployed, then, in this framework of
thought, we may expect to put him back to work by increasing aggregate demand,
regardless of what we happen to spend the money for, whether it be cosmetics or
computers.
This stark
simplicity exists, you see, because aggregate output is a simple increasing
function of aggregate labor employed:
Q = f (L), where dQ/dL > 0.
Note that this
“aggregate production function” has only one input, aggregate labor. The
workers seemingly produce without the aid of capital! If pressed, the vulgar
Keynesian admits that the workers use capital, but he insists that the capital
stock may be taken as “given” and fixed in the short run. And ― which is highly
important ― his whole apparatus of thought is intended exclusively to help him
understand this short run. In the long run, he may insist, we are, as Keynes
quipped, “all dead”; or he may simply deny that the long run is what we get
when we place a series of short runs back to back. The vulgar Keynesian in
effect treats living for the moment, and only for it, as a major virtue. At any
given time, the future may safely be left to take care of itself.
The rate of
interest
The vulgar Keynesian may care about the rate of interest, but only in a restricted sense. For him, the rate of interest is the “price of money,” that is, the price paid for borrowing money. Such borrowing is always good, and more of it is better, because individuals use borrowed money to purchase consumer goods, thereby “creating jobs.” Hence, the lower the rate of interest, the more people will borrow and spend, and the better the economy will function, again so long as any unemployment exists anywhere in the country. Because some unemployment always exists, the vulgar Keynesian always wants the rate of interest to be lower than it is. If it can be lowered artificially by central-bank action, he strongly favors such action.
The vulgar Keynesian may care about the rate of interest, but only in a restricted sense. For him, the rate of interest is the “price of money,” that is, the price paid for borrowing money. Such borrowing is always good, and more of it is better, because individuals use borrowed money to purchase consumer goods, thereby “creating jobs.” Hence, the lower the rate of interest, the more people will borrow and spend, and the better the economy will function, again so long as any unemployment exists anywhere in the country. Because some unemployment always exists, the vulgar Keynesian always wants the rate of interest to be lower than it is. If it can be lowered artificially by central-bank action, he strongly favors such action.
He does not
understand what the rate of interest really is. He fails to comprehend that it
is a crucial relative price ― namely, the price of goods
available now relative to goods available in the future. Remember: he does not
think in terms of relative prices at all, so it is entirely natural that he
fails to recognize how the rate of interest affects the choice between current
consumption and saving (that is, making possible more future consumption by not
consuming current income). In a free market, a reduction in the rate of
interest reflects a desire to shift more consumption from the present to the
future.
A free market would
comprise private suppliers and demanders of loanable funds, and the prevailing
market rate of interest would be that at which the amount demanders want to
borrow equals the amount suppliers want to lend. Both borrowers and lenders,
however, are making their choices in the light of their “time preference,”
which is to say, the rate of which they are willing to trade present goods for
future goods. People with a “high rate of time preference” are keen to consume
now, rather than later, and to induce them to give up present consumption,
borrowers must compensate them by paying a high rate of interest for the use of
their funds.
Although vulgar Keynesians
recognize that a lower rate of interest will spur business firms to borrow more
money and invest it, they imagine that business investment plans are naturally
volatile and essentially irrational ― driven, as Keynes said, by the
entrepreneurs’ “animal spirits.” Hence, the degree to which investment responds
to a change in the rate of interest is small and may be more or less
disregarded. For them, the importance of the rate of interest is that it
regulates the amount that individuals will borrow to finance their purchases of
consumer goods. Those purchases, in the vulgar Keynesian view, are the
essential element in the determination of how much firms want to produce and
how much they want to invest in expanding their capacity to produce. Again, in this
framework, it matters not what kind of investment takes place: investment is
investment is investment.
Capital and its
structure
As noted already, the vulgar Keynesian views the capital stock as “given.” If he thinks about it at all, he considers it a sort of massive inheritance from the past and assumes that nothing that might be added to or subtracted from it in the short run will change it enough to warrant concern. But if he gives little thought to capital, he gives none at all to its structure: the fine-grained patterns of specialization and interrelation among the countless specific forms of capital in which past saving and investment have become embodied. In his framework of analysis, it matters not whether firms invest in new telephones or new hydroelectric dams: capital is capital is capital.
As noted already, the vulgar Keynesian views the capital stock as “given.” If he thinks about it at all, he considers it a sort of massive inheritance from the past and assumes that nothing that might be added to or subtracted from it in the short run will change it enough to warrant concern. But if he gives little thought to capital, he gives none at all to its structure: the fine-grained patterns of specialization and interrelation among the countless specific forms of capital in which past saving and investment have become embodied. In his framework of analysis, it matters not whether firms invest in new telephones or new hydroelectric dams: capital is capital is capital.
Because the
structure of the capital stock is disregarded ― even sophisticated economists,
such as Frank Knight, have insisted that the capital stock is essentially an
undifferentiated glob of monetary value, any part of which may be substituted
perfectly for any other part of equal monetary value ― no attention is given to
how changes in the rate of interest bring about changes in the structure of the
capital stock. After all, what possible difference can it make? This willful
blindness has caused many economists, including the most recent Nobel laureate,
Paul Krugman, to misinterpret the Austrian theory of the business cycle as a
theory of “overinvestment,” which it definitely is not.
Instead, the theory
pioneered by Ludwig von Mises and F. A. Hayek in the first half of the
twentieth century ― a theory that fell into near-oblivion after the Keynesian
Revolution in macroeconomics ― is a theory of malinvestment,which
is to say, a theory of how an artificially reduced rate of interest leads
business firms to invest in the wrong
kinds of capital ― in
particular, in the longest-lived capital goods, such as residential and
industrial buildings, as opposed to inventories and equipment with a relatively
short life. Thus, in the Austrian view, Fed-induced low rates of interest, like
those between 2002 and 2005, lead firms to overvalue longer-term capital
projects and to shift their investment spending in that direction, producing,
for example, booms in building construction. This shift would make economic
sense if the interest rate had fallen in a free market, thereby signaling that
people wish to defer more consumption by saving more of their current income.
But if people have not in fact changed their preferences in this way and
continue to prefer present consumption relatively as much as before, then
businesses will make mistakes by choosing these kinds of investment projects,
which are, in effect, attempts to anticipate future demands that will never
eventuate. When the projects ultimately begin to fail, the boom that
artificially lowered interest rates set in motion will collapse into a bust,
with attendant bankruptcies and unemployed labor, as unsustainable projects are
liquidated and resources shifted, painfully in many cases, to more viable uses.
Because the vulgar
Keynesian is blind to these micro-distortions and to the need for their
correction in the wake of an artificially induced boom, he will fail to see any
need for bankruptcies and unemployment. He supposes: if only the government
stepped in and used its own deficit spending to make up for the reduced private
investment and consumption spending, then business would be restored to
profitability and workers reemployed without
any economic restructuring.
It comes as no
surprise, then, that people who think along such lines are currently working to
continue a policy that contributed greatly to producing the unsustainable boom
of 2002–2006, namely, subsidized lending to would-be homeowners who cannot meet
normal commercial qualifications for receiving such loans. It does not occur to
the vulgar Keynesians that too many resources have been directed into house and
condo construction and that lending to homeowners who can afford to purchase
homes only if subsidized to do so signals an uneconomic use of resources at the
expense of the taxpayers who, directly or indirectly, finance these subsidies.
Malinvestments and
money pumping
With their great, simple faith in the efficacy of government spending as a macroeconomic balance wheel, vulgar Keynesians disregard malinvestment, past and future, and support government spending in excess of the government’s revenues, the difference being covered by borrowing. Of course, they favor central-bank actions to make such borrowing cheaper for the government. In fact, they chronically prefer “easy money” to more restrictive central-bank policies. As noted previously, they prefer easy money not only because it lowers the cost of financing the government’s deficit spending, but also because it induces individuals to borrow more money and spend it for consumption goods ― such increased consumption spending being viewed as always a good thing, notwithstanding the recent near-zero rate of saving by individuals in the United States. Reflecting on the vulgar Keynesian attitude toward Fed policy, I keep recalling a old country song whose refrain was: “older whiskey, faster horses, younger women, more money.”
With their great, simple faith in the efficacy of government spending as a macroeconomic balance wheel, vulgar Keynesians disregard malinvestment, past and future, and support government spending in excess of the government’s revenues, the difference being covered by borrowing. Of course, they favor central-bank actions to make such borrowing cheaper for the government. In fact, they chronically prefer “easy money” to more restrictive central-bank policies. As noted previously, they prefer easy money not only because it lowers the cost of financing the government’s deficit spending, but also because it induces individuals to borrow more money and spend it for consumption goods ― such increased consumption spending being viewed as always a good thing, notwithstanding the recent near-zero rate of saving by individuals in the United States. Reflecting on the vulgar Keynesian attitude toward Fed policy, I keep recalling a old country song whose refrain was: “older whiskey, faster horses, younger women, more money.”
Vulgar Keynesians
do not spend much time worrying about potential inflation; on the contrary,
they are obsessed with an irrational fear of even the slightest hint of
deflation. If inflation should become an undeniable problem, we may count on
them to support price controls, which, they are convinced on the basis of
sketchy knowledge of such controls during World War II, can be made to work
well.
Regime uncertainty
Vulgar Keynesians are nothing, if not policy activists. Like Franklin D. Roosevelt, they believe that the government should “try something,” and if it doesn’t work, try something else. Better still is that the government try a bunch of things at once, and if they don’t turn the trick, then pour more money into them and try something else, to boot. The eras they esteem as the most glorious ones in U.S. politico-economic history are Roosevelt’s first term as president and Lyndon B. Johnson’s first few years in the presidency. These periods witnessed an outpouring of new government measures to spend, tax, regulate, subsidize, and generally create mischief on an extraordinary scale. The Obama administration’s ambitious plans for government action on many fronts fill vulgar Keynesians with hope that a third such Great Leap Forward is now beginning.
Vulgar Keynesians are nothing, if not policy activists. Like Franklin D. Roosevelt, they believe that the government should “try something,” and if it doesn’t work, try something else. Better still is that the government try a bunch of things at once, and if they don’t turn the trick, then pour more money into them and try something else, to boot. The eras they esteem as the most glorious ones in U.S. politico-economic history are Roosevelt’s first term as president and Lyndon B. Johnson’s first few years in the presidency. These periods witnessed an outpouring of new government measures to spend, tax, regulate, subsidize, and generally create mischief on an extraordinary scale. The Obama administration’s ambitious plans for government action on many fronts fill vulgar Keynesians with hope that a third such Great Leap Forward is now beginning.
The vulgar
Keynesian does not understand that policy activism itself works against
economic prosperity by creating what I call “regime uncertainty,” a pervasive
uncertainty about the very nature of the impending economic order, especially
about how the government will treat private property rights in the future. This
kind of uncertainty especially discourages investors from putting money into
long-term projects. Such investment, which almost disappeared after 1929, did
not recover until after World War II. More than one observer has commented in
recent weeks that regime uncertainty has arisen recently from the government’s
frenetic series of bailouts, capital infusions, emergency loans, takeovers,
stimulus packages, and other extraordinary measures crammed into a period of
less than a year, many of them into the past six months. With the commencement
of the Obama administration, prospects appear favorable for a continuation of
this kind of frantic policy activism. It cannot help, and it may hurt a great
deal
No comments:
Post a Comment