By Clive Crook
The arc of Europe’s postwar history is turning toward tragedy. It isn’t just that much of
the continent has fallen into a new Great Depression, or that in some countries
things will get worse before they get better. It isn’t even that the whole mess
was avoidable. It’s that the crisis is dividing Europe along the very lines the
European project was intended to erase.
Decades of cliches about European solidarity and the
European idea are being held up to ridicule. The argument that Britons,
Germans, Greeks, Italians and Spaniards are instinctive cultural partners whose
commonalities transcend their obvious differences and historical enmities --
that “Europe” is a real community, not just a heavily worked-over Brussels blueprint
-- turns out to be, let’s say, disputable.
Ancient stereotypes frame conversation about the
crisis. Germans are bossy and severe. Italians are idle. Greeks are corrupt.
Brits are arrogant. The French are vain. So much for 60 years of European unification.
Germany in particular is coming in for bashing, not just in Greece, where cartoonists have brushed up on their swastikas, but in Italy, Spain and other countries suffering the stress of a German-directed drive to restore Europe’s public finances.
Walking Alone
Until recently, Germany could claim to be expressing
the consensus of rich northern Europe, but no longer. In a union that was
intended, not least by Germany’s own leaders, to bind and subdue Germany within
a larger whole, it instead stands increasingly isolated.
Why did it all go wrong? Three main reasons: French
grandiosity, German shame and a universal law of bureaucratic
self-aggrandizement. These formed a
European Union that was poorly adapted to the stresses the project was sure to
encounter. The EU was unlucky that the crisis came when it did - - before
national loyalties had diminished and an emerging EU identity had begun to take
their place. Yet the EU’s designers had some sense of the risk they were
inevitably running. They gambled and lost.
The overriding goal for a Europe in ruins after 1945 was to create a secure zone of peace and
prosperity. Reconciliation between France and Germany, formerly bitter enemies and sure to be the dominant
economic entities in a new Europe, was vital. As a matter of the highest
priority, the two countries formed a close alliance, and began building a new
united Europe around it. They started modestly in 1951 with the European Coal
and Steel Community, but entertained bigger ambitions at the outset. As early
as 1957, the Treaty
of Rome enshrined the notion of
“ever closer union.” This became the organizing principle for Europe’s
subsequent evolution.
The path not taken was that of an enhanced free-trade
area, a zone of economic cooperation among sovereign states, a kind of
NAFTA-plus. According to France’s thinking, if Europe was to compete and engage
on equal terms with the U.S., it would need to aim higher than that.
Ultimately, a United States of Europe was the goal.
From an early stage, Europe hoped to integrate
politically as well as through trade and commerce. As the European Economic
Community came into being, it took in new members and began to develop a thin
yet feverishly proliferating European layer of government, complete with
parliament and executive. These two drives were in tension. Members of an
ever-widening union had less in common than countries in the advanced-economy
core, making political and economic integration ever harder.
A Bold Moment
Germany mainly wanted a broader union -- to surround
itself with friendly states, even if they were at very different stages of
economic development than those at the European core. France sought especially
a deeper political union, one that would subdue German economic power and give
Paris more reach. Compromising, the two former foes chose to broaden and deepen
at once.
The critical juncture was reached in talks for the Maastricht Treaty of 1992. This provided for European
Monetary Union, the boldest step yet.
As you would expect, France was keen on the new single
currency: This was deepening with a vengeance. Under then- existing
arrangements, French monetary policy was in practice constrained by the choices
of Germany’s mighty central bank. France had no vote on the Bundesbank’s board,
but its interests would be recognized by the European Central Bank. Back then, it saw monetary union as adding to, not
subtracting from, its monetary sovereignty.
More gloriously -- and what is France for, if not la
gloire? -- the single currency advanced the goal of a Europe fit to contend
with the U.S. in global affairs. The dollar needed a rival. Theeuro would be it. A truly single European market,
which the EU had resolved to build, needed to eliminate exchange-rate risk, and
that required a single currency. What better way to incubate a European sense
of identity than to create such a currency?
As before, Germany viewed deepening more skeptically.
Polls told the government that, had Germany’s constitution permitted a
referendum on dropping its esteemed mark, the country would have rejected the
idea. But Chancellor Helmut Kohl gave greater weight to other considerations.
Germany’s sudden enlargement to the east was stirring concern. Kohl wanted to
offer reassurance. This was not Deutschland ueber
Alles, you understand. There’s no
going back to that shameful past. See, we’ll surrender the mark to prove it.
Germany acquiesced in the annihilation of its currency out of meekness.
Yes. That’s ironic.
Central Banking Politics
There was another factor, almost as laughable in
hindsight. A view had gained ground that central banking was above politics.
The goal of monetary
policy was simple -- price stability
-- and the means purely technocratic. The old Keynesian idea that governments
could trade a bit of inflation for a spurt of faster growth stood discredited.
If choices like that ever arose, central banking would be political; but such
choices don’t arise, so monetary policy should be held above the fray.
That’s why leaders weren’t too worried that Europe’s
democratic underpinnings, including its arrangements for fiscal policy, were so
much weaker than those of a typical currency- issuing nation-state. Actually,
they thought, this was a good thing. The EU’s governance deficit would make the
ECB all the more independent. Left alone, it could do its job better and
without controversy.
Nice theory.
This crisis has proved that central banking is a
branch of politics. Under some extreme circumstances, such as the ones we’re
in, monetary policy is really just fiscal policy by other means -- as when a
central bank engages in “quantitative easing” and takes government debt onto
its books. Strictly speaking, again to underline its independence, the ECB was
forbidden to do that, but out of necessity it has lately found ways around the
prohibition. Many economists are now calling for more QE.
In addition, with economies across the euro area
diverging, the supposed simplicity of the stable-prices goal has evaporated.
Price stability in Germany means depression in Greece. But the euro area can have only one monetary policy. Setting it involves
choices that are as political as they come - - but no clear line of democratic
accountability connects the ECB and the EU’s citizens or governments.
Central-bank independence aside, economists drew
attention to the fragility of the euro system’s design from the start. Most presciently,
Harvard’s Martin Feldstein stressed that as economic performance differed
from one country to the next, a single currency would pit winners against
losers, and Europe lacked both the political machinery and the democratic
legitimacy to mediate these disputes. How right he was.
Passing the Burden
The standoff between Germany and its allies with
fiscal austerity on one side and the distressed peripheral economies of Greece,
Ireland, Portugal and Spain on the other comes down to a fight about who bears what burden.
German taxpayers are unwilling to subsidize what they see as
their reckless and feckless EU partners. If this reluctance brings the ceiling
down, it may do Germany more harm than good. You can understand it nonetheless.
Since Europe’s national solidarities look more entrenched than ever, you can
also understand resentment in Greece and elsewhere at being dictated to by
Berlin.
One way of describing Europe’s dysfunction is to say
that economic integration, which sped up with the euro’s arrival, got too far
out in front of political integration. Although that’s true, you would be wrong
to conclude that political integration could have moved much faster. Successive
treaties have run into mounting popular resistance to the transfer of
decision-making power to the EU. Across Europe, politics is still resolutely
national. To many Spaniards, Madrid seems remote, let alone Brussels -- and a similar mindset applies to
most other EU members.
For that reason, adopting the single currency was
always going to be a risk, but it didn’t need to be as risky as it proved.
National governments understood what the economic demands of the euro would be,
then spent more than a decade doing nothing about them. Successive Greek
governments not only overborrowed but also cooked the books to hide the fact.
Greece was an outlier only in that latter respect. Everywhere, complacency about
the safety of sovereign debt was total. For years governments borrowed, and
creditors lent, as though Greek (or Italian or Spanish) debt was as safe as
Germany’s.
That bad behavior was compounded by the failure to
align financial regulation with monetary union. The single currency fostered
deep financial integration across the EU -- one of the things that make exiting
the single currency so difficult. But progress toward a consistent EU-wide
system of financial regulation has been slow.
Continental Drift
Labor markets also remain more national than
continental, leaving workers and businesses at the mercy of the EU’s
imperfectly synchronized business cycles. Migration is permitted in theory, but
can be difficult in practice because pension arrangements and labor
certifications aren’t easily portable. Anyway, how many Frenchmen want to live
in Britain? Or vice versa?
Powerful unions and broken wage-setting systems let
labor costs get out of hand, and created a widening competitiveness gap between
Germany and southern Europe, the main underlying cause of the peripheral
countries’ current plight. Until the crisis intervened, labor-market craziness
as notorious as Spain’s -- where a dual system of permanent and disposable
workers has driven the unemployment
rate to 25 percent -- was
left unattended.
The EU’s executive arm, the European Commission, is
much to blame for this neglect. For years it focused on enlarging and
complicating its areas of competence (I’m using the term in its technical
sense) but failed to prioritize the issues that would make or break the
currency union. Its pathological zeal to standardize product-market regulation
fueled resistance to more rule from Brussels -- resistance it then deflected by
spraying regional development funds hither and yon. Its intrusiveness contrived
to be both threatening and absurd. The commission thrived on tasks that neither
made the euro system safer nor prepared the EU for the economic stresses of the
crash.
The ultimate result is the fateful choice that
confronts Europe in the coming days and weeks. Already this month, a breakup of
the euro system has gone from being unthinkable to becoming a planned-for
contingency. The immediate question is whether Greece will exit. Europe’s
leaders would hope to stop the rot there. But if a “Grexit” happens, attention
will turn instantly to which country goes next. To stop the system unraveling
with who knows what consequences, the EU may have to take the strides toward
deeper union that Germany has been resisting since this crisis exploded: joint
guarantees of sovereign debt and unlimited intervention by the ECB.
The problem is, that’s fiscal union. It commits the EU
to potentially enormous transfers among its members, and makes them explicit.
Can there be fiscal union of that sort without political union? And do Europe’s
divided nations -- the bossy Germans, idle Italians, arrogant Brits and vain
French -- actually want to be one country? Back in Maastricht in 1992, the
Treaty of European Union arranged things so that those questions would one day
have to be answered. Sooner than anybody bargained for, and before Europe was
anything like ready, that day has come.
No comments:
Post a Comment