by Carolina Carmenes Cavia and
David Howden
With victories over the
Germans in the 2008 European Football Championship and during the 2010 World
Cup, there is little doubt that the Spaniards have the upper hand on the soccer
field. Yet while Spaniards have had much to cheer about in the soccer world
over the last five years, the economic situation is a world removed.
Spanish unemployment is now
hovering around 23 percent, with over 50 percent of youths jobless. Only around
6 percent of Germans are without work, almost the lowest level in the country since
reunification. This divide solidifies Spain's position among the
worst-performing economies of the continent, and Germany's vaunted position as
among the best.
Yet such a situation might seem paradoxical. One could, for example, look at the wage rates of the respective workers and find that low-cost Spaniards are much more affordable. Profit-maximizing businesses should be expanding their facilities to take advantage of the opportunity the Spanish crisis has provided and eschew higher-cost German labor.
While fixating on nominal labor costs might provide a compelling case for a bright Spanish future, delving into the details provides some darker figures.
One of the main differences
between Germany's and Spain's labor markets is their minimum-wage rates. A
Spanish minimum-wage worker can expect to earn about €633 per month. Germany on
the other hand enforces no across-the-board minimum wage except in isolated
professions — construction workers, roofers, and electricians, as examples.[1]
German employees are free to
negotiate their salaries with their employers, without any price-fixing
intervention by the government in the form of wage control. (This is not to
imply that the German labor market is completely unhampered — jobs are
cartelized by industry each with its own wage controls. While this
cartelization is not perfect, it does at least recognize that a
one-size-fits-all minimum-wage policy is not optimal for the whole country.)
As an example of the German
approach to wages, consider the case of a construction worker. In eastern
Germany this worker would make a minimum wage of around €9 per hour. His
counterpart in western Germany would earn considerably more — almost €11 an
hour.[2] This
difference allows for productivity differences to be priced separately or local
supply-and-demand conditions to influence wages. Working for five days at eight
hours a day would yield this German worker anywhere from €360 to €440.
It is obvious that the German
weekly wage is almost as high as the monthly Spanish one. What is less obvious
is why Germans do not move their facilities to lower-cost Spain.
As the old saying goes, "the more expensive you are to fire, the
more expensive you are to hire." If a Spanish company decides to lay off
an employee, the severance payment for most labor contracts (afiniquito in Spanish) will amount to 32 days for
each year the employee has worked with the company. Although this process is
not simple in Germany either, there is no legal severance requirement that
companies must pay to redundant workers. The sole requirement is for ample
notice to be given, sometimes up to six months in advance. If a Spanish company hires a
worker who does not work out as intended, a substantial cost will be incurred
in the future to offload the employee. Employers know this, and when hiring
workers they exercise caution accordingly, lest this unfortunate and
unplanned-for future materialize.
These factors make the
perceived or expected cost of labor at times higher in Spain than in Germany,
despite the actual monetary cost being lower in euro terms. This effect has
been especially pronounced since the adoption of the common currency over a
decade ago. As we can see below, the average cost of German labor is largely
unmoved since 2000, while Spanish labor has increased
about 25 percent over the
same period.
When hiring a worker, the nominal wage is only half the story. The employer also needs to know how productive that worker will be. Even after we factor for the extra costs on Spanish labor, a German worker could be more costly. A firm would still choose to hire that worker if his or her productivity was greater.
When hiring a worker, the nominal wage is only half the story. The employer also needs to know how productive that worker will be. Even after we factor for the extra costs on Spanish labor, a German worker could be more costly. A firm would still choose to hire that worker if his or her productivity was greater.
As we can see in the two
figures below, over the last decade a large divergence has emerged between the
two countries. While German productivity has more or less kept pace with its
small increases in wage rates, the Spanish story is remarkably different.
Productivity has lagged, meaning that on a real basis Spanish laborers are much
more costly today than they were just
10 years ago.
In his book The Tragedy of the Euro, Philipp Bagus mentions a similar phenomenon. Bagus points to the combination of (1) the rising labor costs that result from eurozone inflation and (2) divergent productivity rates between the countries as a source of imbalance. Indeed, inflation has been one driver of rising (and destabilizing) wages in the periphery of Europe, and especially in Spain. Others include, as we have noted here, minimum wages, regulatory burdens, and severance packages that increase the potential cost of labor.
In his book The Tragedy of the Euro, Philipp Bagus mentions a similar phenomenon. Bagus points to the combination of (1) the rising labor costs that result from eurozone inflation and (2) divergent productivity rates between the countries as a source of imbalance. Indeed, inflation has been one driver of rising (and destabilizing) wages in the periphery of Europe, and especially in Spain. Others include, as we have noted here, minimum wages, regulatory burdens, and severance packages that increase the potential cost of labor.
In either case the effect is
the same: wage rates do not necessarily reflect the labor itself, but rather
the regulation surrounding it. In Spain, this translates to noncompetitive
wages. It is important to remember, though, that this does not imply that the
labor itself is necessarily uncompetitive — it is price dependent after all.
Every good has its price, even
labor. When prices are hindered from fluctuating to clear markets, imbalances
occur. In labor markets those imbalances are unemployed people. Policies such
as a one-size-fits-all minimum wage and high mandated severance packages keep
the price of Spanish labor above what it needs to be to clear the market.
Until something is done to
ease these policies, Spanish labor will remain uncompetitively priced. Until
Spanish labor costs can be repriced competitively, Spain's masses will need to
endure stifling levels of unemployment.
No comments:
Post a Comment