BY JAMES PETHOKOUKIS
America needs to break up its biggest banks, but not for reasons likely to
give a tingle to Occupy Wall Street’s remnant rabble (or its Great Everywhere
Spirit, Senate candidate Elizabeth Warren of Massachusetts). This isn’t about
some political exercise in election-year demonization. Bankers, as a class,
aren’t villains. They’re not “banksters” grifting money from middle-income
pockets. And they’re certainly not vampire squids on the collective face of
humanity, as Rolling Stone writer Matt Taibbi has infamously
described Goldman Sachs. And while it might be rhetorical overkill to say
they’re “doing God’s work,” as Goldman boss Lloyd Blankfein has put it, bankers
do fulfill a critical economic function. Bankers, not bureaucrats, are supposed
to be the efficient allocators of capital in America’s market-based economy.
They connect people who have spare dough to those who need a bit of spare
dough, such as entrepreneurs looking to start a business or companies looking
to grow one. We need lots of successful banks, and we need smart folks to run
them.
But America doesn’t need 20 banks with combined assets equal to nearly 90 percent of the U.S. economy, or five mega-banks—JPMorgan Chase, Bank of America, Citigroup, Wells Fargo, and Goldman Sachs—with combined assets equal to almost 60 percent of national output, three times what they were in the 1990s. That amount of complexity and financial concentration—which has grown worse since the passage of Dodd-Frank—is a current and continuing threat to the health of the U.S. economy. Now don’t blame market failure or unintended results of deregulation. Banks that big and complex and interconnected are both the unsurprising outcome of Washington’s 30-year expansion of the federal safety net and the cause of its ongoing existence. When you combine a “too big to fail” guarantee from Uncle Sam with the natural human tendency toward irrational exuberance, you have the key elements in place for another unaffordable financial crisis.
Bubbles are nothing new. And the root cause of the financial crisis of
2008-2009 may have been no different than what drove manias for Dutch tulips in
17th-century Holland, shares of the South Sea Company in 18th-century England,
or dot-com stocks in 1990s America. This time around, the vehicle for the
market’s mania was an outbreak of cockeyed optimism about housing
prices—among both lenders and borrowers—and their inability to ever
decline. A new study from the Federal Reserve banks of Atlanta and Boston, “Why
Did So Many People Make So Many Ex Post Bad Decisions: The
Causes of the Foreclosure Crisis,” explains it this way: “Bubbles do not need
securitization, government involvement or nontraditional lending products to
get started. . . . If the problem was some collective, self-fulfilling mania,
[a new round of regulations] will not work.”
The supporters of the Dodd-Frank financial reform law, the study suggests,
diagnosed and treated the financial crisis like it was an outbreak of malaria,
a preventable disaster caused by a disease whose pathologies are well
understood. Change this or that incentive via this or that financial regulation
and the problem is far less likely to repeat.
But that approach is as much a case of mass delusion as the one that
afflicted all those owners in 2007 of sure-thing mortgage-backed securities or
mini-mansions in reclaimed Nevada desert. MIT economist Andrew Lo reviewed 21
books about the financial crisis and concluded that “like the characters inRashomon,
we may never settle on a single narrative that explains all the facts; such a
‘super-narrative’ may not even exist.”
Lo finds the empirical evidence for many so-called facts that influenced
Dodd-Frank to be unclear at best. We all know, of course, that Wall Street
compensation was too focused on making a quick buck from short-term trading
profits. Yet Lo inconveniently points out that big bank CEOs’ aggregate stock
and option holdings were more than eight times the value of their annual
compensation, making it “improbable that a rational CEO knew in advance of an
impending financial crash, or knowingly engaged in excessively risky behavior.”
And a rational CEO of a key Wall Street player also knew that if he did
make some cataclysmic mistake, Uncle Sam was there to cushion the landing.
Indeed, the bigger the firm and the more enmeshed it was in the financial
system, the more likely the government backstop would be there. The riskier
banks were, paradoxically, the safer they were—at least for bondholders. So
why wouldn’t “rational CEOs” try to increase their return on equity by lowering
capital levels, increasing leverage, and finding new, profitable lines of
business? They might be violating their duty to bank shareholders if they
didn’t. “The consequence of expanding the safety net to an ever-increasing
range of activities is to invite a repeat of our most recent crisis,” said
Thomas Hoenig, vice chairman of FDIC and former president of the Kansas City
Fed, in a speech last year.
But treating the financial crisis like a malaria outbreak uses the wrong
model. Better, say the authors of that Fed bank study, to view the meltdown as
a different sort of noneconomic catastrophe: “Science has a theory of why
earthquakes occur, but quakes strike without warning, and there is nothing we
can do to prevent them. Even so, policymakers can mitigate their consequences.”
Or as Hayek might have put it, not only is government unable to predict the
future, the world is too complicated for it to really have much useful
understanding of what’s going on right now. Regulators are always a day late
and a dollar short. Indeed, despite Dodd-Frank, the biggest banks still have a
sizable funding edge over their smaller rivals. Markets still perceive them as
too big to fail.
So how do you (a) make the financial system more shockproof when the next
economic earthquake hits, (b) reduce the likelihood of expensive taxpayer
bailouts, and (c) ensure the banks themselves don’t cause the next crisis?
Hoenig, for one, would only allow banks to engage in traditional activities
that are well understood and are based on long-term customer relationships so
borrowers and lenders are on the same page: commercial banking, underwriting
securities, and asset management services. Banks would be barred from
broker-dealer activities, making markets in derivatives or securities, trading
securities or derivatives for their own accounts or for customers, and
sponsoring hedge funds or private equity funds. The result would be banks that
are smaller, simpler, safer. Not only would they be less likely to spark
financial crisis because management would know government might let them fail,
the cost of failure to taxpayers would be less.
Of course, some will argue that we need large, complex financial
institutions and that their very existence is proof of that. Who are the know-it-all
breaker-uppers to say we don’t? But that size and complexity is itself more a
result of crony capitalism than of market forces. It’s little wonder, then,
that the preponderance of the evidence is that all the supposed benefits from
supersized banks and their economies of scale are outweighed by the risks of
disaster they generate. Take this 2011 study from the University of Minnesota:
“Our calculations indicate that the cost to the economy as a whole due to
increased systemic risk is of an order of magnitude larger than the potential
benefits due to any economies of scale when banks are allowed to be large.
. . . This suggests that the link between TBTF banks and financial crises
needs to be broken. One way to achieve that is to break the largest banks into
much smaller pieces.”
There are other options, of course. We could just put a hard cap on bank
size. But there’s no clear evidence what that size limit should be. Besides,
while the failure of a big bank creates a big economic impact, it’s not
necessarily size that makes a bank potentially dangerous as much as what a bank
does. Others want to treat systemic risk as an externality like pollution and
tax it. Nothing wrong with that in theory. Former presidential candidate Jon
Huntsman proposed just such a plan and would have used the revenue to cut
corporate taxes. The riskier the activities the bank engages in, the higher the
tax. But this again requires too much knowledge on the part of regulators to
precisely gauge the riskiness of activities or assets and levy an appropriate tax.
Again, Hayek. A risk tax also creates new opportunities for Wall Street
lobbying.
What about just getting Washington out of the banking business entirely? No
deposit insurance for investors. No Federal Reserve as a lender of last resort.
Lenders would be more vigilant, bank execs more scared, moral hazard
eliminated. But explaining to the American public the need to do away with
these two longtime features of both the American economy and advanced economies
globally would take time, time we may not have. And if a crisis should occur,
politicians would still be strongly tempted to start cutting checks. And
America cannot afford another economy-crushing financial crisis, not now and
probably not for years. In 2007, publicly held federal debt as a share of national
economic output was 36 percent. In 2012, it will be roughly double that level,
73 percent, and likely heading even higher. And once you add what Uncle Sam
owes in social insurance entitlements, total U.S. debt is bigger than the
entire economy, 103 percent of GDP. That amount of indebtedness is well past
the 90 percent level identified by economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth
Rogoff as a serious drag on long-term growth. And like the debt, unemployment
is also already at an intolerable level and likely to remain historically high
for years to come given the slow pace of recovery.
Also unlike those ideas on libertarian wish lists, breaking up the banks
has some actual legislative momentum thanks to JPMorgan’s huge trading losses
on its botched hedging strategy. Banking analyst Jaret Seiberg of Guggenheim
Securities’ Washington Research Group calls a bipartisan bank breakup movement
along the lines Hoenig outlines both a “serious threat” and the top issue
facing the sector for the rest of the year. “The Republican response to
Dodd-Frank’s overkill is to break up the banks. The far left also wants to
break up the big banks. The issue with the JPMorgan hedging mess is that it
empowers the far left and the far right to pursue their agendas while the silent
majority in the middle ducks for political cover.” In fact, what banking
analysts call a “serious threat” should strike those outside the management of
big banks—left, right, and center—as a “serious opportunity.”
Breaking up the biggest banks would allow markets to work better, by
cutting down on crony capitalist rent-seeking by big money from big government.
It would also reduce the moral hazard created by Washington’s too big to fail
policy. Ending too big to fail isn’t a policy conservatives should shy away
from—even if some on the left support it too.
No comments:
Post a Comment