Europe faces
withered economies and double-digit unemployment rates from Ireland to Italy.
Now, after yet another summit, Europe’s wise men and women have hit upon yet
another fix. This time, they’re pushing universal deposit insurance across the
Eurozone, in which the people of any nation in trouble would be bailed out by
people in other euro nations: Spanish bank depositors, for example, would pay
for rescues of Greek bank depositors if Greek banks failed, and vice versa. The
new idea, like many before it, ignores the problem at the root of the European
crisis: the euro itself.
Greece, Spain, and
others are in trouble because they—and their banks—borrowed so much money so
recklessly during the boom years. Global money managers thought these nations’
euro membership made investment in their debt a sure thing. Strong countries
like Germany, the thinking went, would never countenance defaults on government
or big-bank debt issued in the common currency. Easy money, in turn, allowed
much of Europe to avoid hard questions on unaffordable retirement benefits and
inflexible labor markets.
When the bust
came, the euro fetters compounded the problem. Fifty years ago, a country like
Greece would have dealt with a debt burden by printing up more money to pay off
bonds in cheaper drachmas. The subsequent fall in the value of the Greek
currency would have encouraged foreigners to buy Greek products and to visit
Greece, ameliorating the country’s economic contraction. Of course, such a
solution wouldn’t have been good for Greek savers, and it would present
tremendous risks if carried too far.
What Greece and the rest of Europe are doing today, though, is hardly an improvement. Greece took the rest of the world on an excruciating two-year journey to its debt default earlier this year. The continued doubt about whether the country can pay back its debt has prolonged economic uncertainty, leading to more joblessness: 21.7 percent of Greeks are out of work. The Greek saga has also stolen attention from other national crises. Greece is tiny; Spain and Ireland are not. The Spanish banking system, with $717.1 billion in liabilities, is nine times as large as Greece’s; the Irish banking system is nearly six times as large. Banks in both nations splurged on property loans during the boom, and both nations, as they struggle to repay bad debt, now have extremely high unemployment rates—14.2 percent in Ireland and a truly scary 24.3 percent in Spain.
Since 2008, the
eurocrats have acted only fecklessly to address these issues. Europe’s
“leaders”—Germany and France—want Ireland and Spain to force their taxpayers to
bail out the lenders who financed the binge. The leaders looked on last year
when Spain allowed one flailing bank, Bankia, to snooker small depositors into
becoming “little bankers” and buying stakes in the bank to prop it up, exposing
them to loss. But the bailouts-at-any-cost method is no longer working. Two
weeks ago, when Spain announced it would borrow money from Europe’s rescue fund
to prop up its banks, investors weren’t reassured: they sent interest rates on
Spain’s government debt soaring.
German and French
leaders have never questioned the morality of forcing taxpayers and workers to
sacrifice so that investors in banks don’t have to. Nor have they been honest
about the choice they have made. They’ve never said, for instance, that for as
long as Europe keeps servicing bad debt, growth will remain slow to
non-existent, and there’s little anyone can do about it—unless Germany, France,
and other strong countries want to make massive, open-ended fiscal transfers to
weaker countries.
Europe’s latest
announcement is just another distraction. Political leaders now say that they
want at least some investors in banks to shoulder the losses, just not right
away—that would scare the delicate bankers. Perhaps by 2018 or 2019 they’ll be
ready. As one step in that process, Europe will think about implementing an
EU-wide deposit scheme: if a bank in Greece or Spain (or France or Germany)
fails, and its sophisticated investors take losses, the rest of Europe could
step in to make sure that the failed bank’s small depositors didn’t lose money.
“We support the intention to consider concrete steps toward a more integrated
financial architecture, encompassing banking supervision, resolution and
recapitalization, and deposit insurance,” the leaders of the G-20 international
summit, including President Obama, said Tuesday of Europe’s effort.
Europe would model
its deposit insurance on America’s Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and
understandably so. The FDIC works well when Washington allows it to. When a
bank fails, its big bondholders and other creditors are supposed to be subject
to financial loss, ensuring market discipline. But thanks to the money from a
fee levied on all bank deposits, small depositors are protected from losing
money. Such loss would be unwarranted punishment of people who never intended
to risk their money on an investment, only put it in an account for
safekeeping.
Europe is missing
something crucial about the U.S. method, though. American deposit insurance
works because the United States is one country with one currency. Europe, on
the other hand, is many countries with one currency. A bank may fail in
California, costing banks elsewhere money. But the state of California is not
going to decree, suddenly, that it is no longer in the dollar.
Greece or Spain,
on the other hand, could pull out of the euro, and the longer economic
stagnation continues, the greater that risk grows. A bank has failed, under any
reasonable definition, if its depositors can’t withdraw their funds in the same
currency in which they deposited them. In such a case, under an EU-wide deposit
scheme, the bank depositors in a country that has just deserted the euro could
then call on Europe to give them back their money in euros, not in the nation’s
new currency.
Such a wrinkle could
quickly change politicians’ and voters’ motivations. Consider that voters in
Greece chose implicitly Sunday, with their vote for a relatively moderate
party, to stay in the euro. Greeks voted the way they did partly because they
don’t want to get stuck with an inflated currency that wipes out their savings.
But what if Greeks knew their savings were safe, because Germany had pledged to
protect their euro-denominated deposits? They might have voted differently.
Sure, European
leaders could exclude forced currency conversions from their cross-border
insurance scheme. But then the cross-border deposit insurance wouldn’t really
be deposit insurance. Why should a Greek saver indirectly pay a fee, through
his bank, for protection, when the biggest risk he faces is the currency risk
that isn’t covered? Moreover, any such provision would send a signal to the
rest of the world that Europe is acutely worried about currency pull-outs.
Europe, then, is
right back where it started. European leaders must first deal with the tens of
billions of dollars in bad debt crushing their people. For now, the best
protection for European savers would be economic growth. Europe can consider
cross-border deposit insurance only after (and if) the Continent graduates to
closer fiscal union that ensures the euro’s survival—not before.
No comments:
Post a Comment