It is now 32
years, nearly a third of a century, since Julian Simon nailed his theses to the
door of the eco-pessimist church by publishing his famous article in
Science magazine: “resources, population, environment: an oversupply of bad
news”. It is also 40 years since The Limits to Growth and 50 years since
Silent Spring, plenty long enough to reflect on whether the world
has conformed to Malthusian pessimism
or Simonian optimism.
Before I go on,
I want to remind you just how viciously Simon was attacked for saying
that he thought the bad news was being exaggerated and the good news
downplayed. Verbally at least Simon’s treatment was every bit as rough as
Martin Luther’s. Simon was called an imbecile, a moron, silly, ignorant, a
flat-earther, a member of the far right, a Marxist. “Could the
editors have found someone to review Simon’s manuscript who had
to take off his shoes to count to 20?” said Paul Ehrlich.
Erhlich together
with John Holdren then launched a blistering critique, accusing Simon of lying
about electricity prices having fallen. It turned out they were basing their
criticism on a typo in a table, as Simon discovered by calling the table’s
author. To which Ehrlich replied: “what scientist would phone the author of a
standard source to make sure there were no typos in a series of numbers?”
Answer: one who
likes to get his facts right.
Yet for all the invective, his critics have never laid a glove on Julian Simon then or later. I cannot think of a single significant fact, data point or even prediction where he was eventually proved badly wrong. There may be a few trivia that went wrong, but the big things are all right. Read that 1980 article again today and you will see what I mean.
I want to draw a
few lessons from Julian Simon’s battle with the Malthusian minotaur, and
from my own foolhardy decision to follow in his footsteps– and those of
Bjorn Lomborg, Ron Bailey, Indur Goklany, Ian Murray, Myron Ebell and
others – into the labyrinth a couple of decades later.
Consider the words
of the publisher’s summary of The Limits to Growth: “Will this be the world
that your grandchildren will thank you for? A world where industrial
production has sunk to zero. Where population has suffered a catastrophic
decline. Where the air, sea, and land are polluted beyond
redemption. Where civilization is a distant memory. This is the world
that the computer forecasts.”
Again and
again Simon was right and his critics were wrong.
Would it not be
nice if just one of those people who called him names piped up and admitted
it? We optimists have won every intellectual argument and yet we have made
no difference at all. My daughter’s textbooks trot out the same old Malthusian
dirge as mine did.
What makes it so
hard to get the message across?
I think it boils
down to five adjectives: ahistorical, finite, static, vested and
complacent. The eco-pessimist view ignores history,
misunderstands finiteness, thinks statically, has a vested interest in doom and
is complacent about innovation.
People have very
short memories. They are not just ignoring, but unaware of, the poor
track record of eco-pessimists. For me, the fact that each of the scares I
mentioned above was taken very seriously at the time, attracting the solemn
endorsement of the great and the good, should prompt real skepticism about
global warming claims today. That’s what motivated me to start asking to
see the actual evidence about climate change. When I did so I could
not find one piece of data – as opposed to a model – that shows either
unprecedented change or change is that is anywhere close to causing real harm.
Yet when I made this point to a climate scientist recently, he promptly and
cheerily said that “the fact that people have been wrong before does not make
them wrong this time” as if this somehow settled the matter for good.
Second, it is
enormously hard for people to grasp Simon’s argument that “Incredible
as it may seem at first, the term “finite” is not only inappropriate but
downright misleading in the context of natural resources”. He went on
“…Because we find new lodes, invent better production methods and
discover new substitutes, the ultimate constraint upon our capacity to
enjoy unlimited raw materials at acceptable prices is knowledge.” This is
a profoundly counterintuitive point.
Yet was there ever
a better demonstration of this truth than the shale gas
revolution? Shale gas was always there; but what made it a resource, as
opposed to not a resource, was knowledge – the practical know-how developed by
George Mitchell in Texas. This has transformed the energy picture of the world.
Besides, as I have
noted elsewhere, it’s the renewable – infinite – resources that have a habit of
running out: whales, white pine forests, buffalo. It’s a startling fact,
but no non-renewable resource has yet come close to exhaustion, whereas lots of
renewable ones have.
And by the way,
have you noticed something about fossil fuels – we are the only creatures that
use them. What this means is that when you use oil, coal or gas, you are not
competing with other species. When you use timber, or crops or tide, or hydro
or even wind, you are. There is absolutely no doubt that the world’s policy of
encouraging the use of bio-energy, whether in the form of timber or
ethanol, is bad for wildlife – it competes with wildlife for land, or
wood or food.
Imagine a world in
which we relied on crops and wood for all our energy and then
along comes somebody and says here’s this stuff underground that we can
use instead, so we don’t have to steal the biosphere’s lunch.
Imagine no more.
That’s precisely what did happen in the industrial revolution.
Third, the
Malthusian view is fundamentally static. Julian Simon’s view is fundamentally
dynamic. Again and again when I argue with greens I find that they simply do
not grasp the reflexive nature of the world, the way in which prices
cause the substitution of resources or the dynamic properties of
ecosystems – the word equilibrium has no place in ecology.
Take malaria. The
eco-pessimists insisted until recently that malaria must get worse in a
warming 21st century world. But, as Paul Reiter kept telling
them to no avail, this is nonsense. Malaria disappeared from North America,
Russia and Europe and retreated dramatically in South America, Asia and Africa
in the twentieth century even as the world warmed. That’s not because the world
got less congenial to mosquitoes. It’s because we moved indoors and drained the
swamps and used DDT and malaria medications and so on. Human beings are a
moving target. They adapt.
But, my fourth
point, another reason Simon’s argument fell on stony ground is that
so many people had and have a vested interest in doom. Though they hate to
admit it, the environmental movement and the scientific
community are vigorous, healthy,
competitive, cut-throat, free markets in which corporate
leviathans compete for donations, grants, subsidies and publicity. The
best way of getting all three is to sound the alarm. If it bleeds it
leads. Good news is no news. Imagine how much money you would get if you
put out an advert saying: “we now think climate change will be
mild and slow, none the less please donate”. The sums concerned
are truly staggering. Greenpeace and WWF, the General Motors and Exxon of the
green movement, between them raise and spend a billion dollars
a year globally. WWF spends $68m alone on educational propaganda. Frankly,
Julian, Bjorn, Ron, Indur, Ian, Myron and I are spitting in the wind.
Yet, fifth,
ironically, a further problem is complacency. The eco-pessimists are the
Panglossians these days, for it is they who think the world will be fine
without developing new technologies. Let’s not adopt GM food – let’s stick with
pesticides. Was there ever a more complacent doctrine than the precautionary
principle: don’t try anything new until you are sure it is safe? As if
the world were perfect. It is we eco-optimists, ironically, who
are acutely aware of how miserable this world still is and how much better we
could make it – indeed how precariously dependent we are on still inventing
ever more new technologies.
I had a good
example of this recently debating a climate alarmist. He insisted that the risk
from increasing carbon dioxide was acute and that therefore we needed to
drastically cut our emissions by 90 percent or so. In vain did I try to point
out that drastically cutting emissions by 90% might do more harm to the poor
and the rain forest than anything the emissions themselves
might do. That we are taking chemotherapy for a cold, putting a
tourniquet round our neck to stop a nosebleed.
My old employer,
the Economist, is fond of a version of Pascal’s wager – namely that however
small the risk of catastrophic climate change, the impact could be so huge
that almost any cost is worth bearing to avert it. I have been trying to
persuade them that the very same logic applies to emissions reduction.
However small is the risk that emissions reduction will lead to planetary
devastation, almost any price is worth paying to prevent that, including the
tiny risk that carbon emissions will destabilize the climate. Just look at
Haiti to understand that getting rid of fossil fuels is a huge environmental
risk.
That’s what I mean
by complacency: complacently assuming that we can decarbonize the
economy without severe ecological harm, complacently assuming that we can
shut down world trade without starving the poor, that we can grow organic
crops for seven billion people without destroying the rain forest.
Having paid homage
to Julian Simon’s ideas, let me end by disagreeing with him on one
thing. At least I think I am disagreeing with him, but I may be wrong. He made
the argument, which was extraordinary and repulsive to me when I first heard it
as a young and orthodox eco-pessimist, that the more people in the
world, the more invention. That people were brains as well as mouths, solutions
as well as problems. Or as somebody once put it: why is the birth of a
baby a cause for concern, while the birth of a calf is a cause for hope?
Now there is a
version of this argument that – for some peculiar reason – is very popular
among academics, namely that the more people there are, the greater the chance
that one of them will be a genius, a scientific or technological Messiah.
Occasionally,
Julian Simon sounds like he is in this camp. And if he were here today, — and
by Zeus, I wish he were – I would try to persuade him that this is not the
point, that what counts is not how many people there are but how well they are
communicating. I would tell him about the new evidence from Paleolithic
Tasmania, from Mesolithic Europe from the Neolithic Pacific, and from the
internet today, that it’s trade and exchange that breeds innovation, through
the meeting and mating of ideas. That the lonely inspired genius is a
myth, promulgated by Nobel prizes and the patent system. This means that
stupid people are just as important as clever ones; that the collective
intelligence that gives us incredible improvements in living standards depends
on people’s ideas meeting and mating, more than on how many people there are.
That’s why a little country like Athens or Genoa or Holland can suddenly lead
the world. That’s why mobile telephony and the internet has no
inventor, not even Al Gore.
Not surprisingly,
academics don’t like this argument. They just can’t get their pointy heads
around the idea that ordinary people drive innovation just by exchanging and
specializing. I am sure Julian Simon got it, but I feel he was still
flirting with the outlier theory instead.
The great human
adventure has barely begun. The greenest thing we can do is innovate. The
most sustainable thing we can do is change. The only limit is
knowledge. Thank you Julian Simon for these insights. And thank
you for this award.
No comments:
Post a Comment