by Philipp Bagus
Recently, there has been an
intense debate in Europe on the TARGET2 system (Trans-EuropeanAutomated Real-time
Gross Settlement ExpressTransfer System 2), which is the joint gross clearing
system of the eurozone.[1] The interpretation of this system and its balances
has provoked divergent opinions. Some economists, most prominently Hans-Werner
Sinn, have argued that TARGET2 amounts to a bailout system. Others have
vehemently denied that. Jürgen Stark of the European Central Bank (ECB) even
said that some commentators could lose their reputation as serious academics by
claiming that TARGET2 functions as a bailout system.
Indeed, TARGET2 debits and
credits have been built up since the beginning of the financial crisis. While
peripheral countries accumulated TARGET2 debits, in April 2012 TARGET2 claims
of the Bundesbank amounted to almost €644 billion. That is almost €8,000 per
German.
But does TARGET2 really amount to an undercover bailout system for unsustainable living standards in the periphery? Let us start our analysis with a simple example of two individuals using a bank to clear their payments.
Person A sells a good or
service to person B for €100. In international trade terms, A has a current
account surplus while B has a current account deficit. A receives a claim or
credit against the bank of €100 when the payment is made (the broken line in
figure 1). B has a debt and owes the bank €100. The debt relationships are
shown by solid arrows pointing in the direction of the debtor.
A now has some money saved in
his bank that he may plan to use, for instance, for retirement. B has to
produce something of value to be able to pay back his debt. A will finally be
paid by B's production of real goods (that may maintain him at retirement).
For A it is important that the
bank's loan to B is secured by a good guarantee or collateral such as a
high-quality security or real estate. In the absence of collateral for B's
loan, problems arise if B does not pay his debt because he dies or for other
reasons. If the bank does not hold other property to make up for the bad loan,
A will be left with a claim against a bankrupt bank.
Of course, if the bank has the
privilege of printing (legal-tender) bank notes, the bank will not go bankrupt
but can pay back A. But A will then be paid back merely in paper, a worthless
claim in our scenario, because B has not produced anything and has died. So what
should A buy with the newly printed paper? A's standard of living will fall at
retirement as his wealth is based just on paper.
Let us now assume that A lives
in Germany and B lives in Spain. Furthermore, we introduce Commerzbank as A's
German bank, and Banco Santander as B's Spanish bank. In addition, we add the
two national central banks and the ECB.
We again assume that A exports
goods worth €100 to B. When the payment is made, A receives a claim against
Commerzbank. A's bank account increases €100. B gets a €100 loan from Banco
Santander (alternatively he could run down his deposit account at Banco
Santander). Commerzbank gets a claim against the Bundesbank (or reduces its
refinancing from it), while Banco Santander increases its refinancing with the Bank
of Spain (or reduces its excess reserves).
On the level of central banks,
the Bundesbank receives a credit against the ECB while the Bank of Spain gets a
debit. Underlying this procedure is an import of goods to Spain that has been
financed by Banco Santander creating new money in form of a loan to B. The
money creation results in TARGET2 debits for the Bank of Spain and TARGET2
credits for the Bundesbank.
Let us compare the TARGET2
method with the financing of imports in a gold standard. In both systems,
import surpluses may be financed by capital imports, i.e., A or Commerzbank
buys a bond from B. If there is no private capital financing in a gold
standard, the import must be paid by transferring gold. In contrast, in the
Eurosystem, import surpluses can simply be financed by producing claims against
the ECB. Instead of gold, the Bundesbank receives TARGET2 credits. While in a
gold standard, the payment of imports (if not financed by private loans) is
limited to the outflow of gold, there is no limit for TARGET2 credits, i.e.,
the import surpluses may be financed without any limit by the creation of Euro
claims.
How do TARGET2 debits and
credits disappear? The balances disappear if A imports from B or if B sells a
bond to A or borrows from him on the private market. There is nothing to assert
against financing the import surplus through private loans or bonds. TARGET2
debits, however, are not private loans but amount to public central-bank loans.
Without TARGET2, someone in the Spanish economy would have had to find private
investors to finance the trade deficit paying potentially high interest rates,
especially if no high-quality collateral for such loans can be provided.
In this sense, the TARGET2
system indeed amounts to a bailout of an uncompetitive economy with too high
prices. Thanks to this bailout mechanism, the country does not have to
deregulate labor markets, and reduce government spending to adjust prices
relatively but can continue its spending spree and maintain its uncompetitive
internal structure.
But are the TARGET2 debits and
credits really never settled? Surprisingly, there is indeed neither a limit for
the TARGET2 bailouts, nor are the accounts ever settled. In contrast, in the
Federal Reserve System debits are backed by gold certificates and each year
balances are settled. If the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond has a debit with
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the former settles its account sending
gold certificates to the latter.[2]
The Eurosystem not only allows
the financing of import surpluses via money creation; it also enables
"capital flights." In the current situation, a default of the Greek
government would bankrupt its banking system. In order to prevent losses, Greek
depositors have sent and are sending their money from accounts at Greek banks
to accounts of banks in Germany and other countries. Through this transfer, the
Greek bank loses reserves while the German one increases its reserves. The
Greek bank increases refinancing from its national central bank (i.e., receives
newly created money) while the German bank can decrease it loans from the
Bundesbank. The Bundesbank earns a TARGET2 credit, the Bank of Greece a TARGET2
debit. If the Greek government defaults, and the Bank of Greece default on its
debits, losses mount for the ECB. Thus, the risk of a Greek default is now
shared by German savers through the TARGET2 credit.
What Is the Essence of TARGET2
Balances?
TARGET2 credits ultimately
represent claims of savers, while TARGET2 debits represent debts of companies,
governments, and individuals. TARGET2 accounts are just a consequence of an
ongoing redistribution and of bailouts. For instance, TARGET2 accounts may
mirror the tragedy of the euro, i.e., the monetization of government deficits.
Take the following example. A Spanish bank creates new money to buy a Spanish
government bond. This allows the Spanish government to maintain its government
spending and to delay reforms of the labor market. It may increase
public-sector wages and unemployment benefits. The competitiveness of the
Spanish economy is hampered due to too high wages resulting in a trade deficit:
a Spanish minister buys a German car. In the beginning, the trade deficit may
be financed by private entities, for instance, by loans from German banks to
Spanish banks. Yet after some time the Spanish banks will run out of good
collateral. The increasing government debts and the overindebtedness of the
private sector reduce the quality of Spanish debt as collateral. At some point,
private investors do not want to continue to finance Spanish banks and the
Spanish trade deficit because they do not have good collateral (we are already
beyond this point). Yet thanks to TARGET2 the party can continue. Spanish banks
can use bad collateral (Spanish government bonds) and refinance with the Bank
of Spain, which accepts Spanish government bonds as collateral for new loans.
As a result of this indirect monetization of government bonds, TARGET2 debits
to the ECB increase. Bad risks (collateral) are shifted to the Eurosystem and socialized.
TARGET2 thereby allows to finance the trade deficit through public central bank
loans.
Not only public debts may be
monetized through the Eurosystem and their risk socialized through TARGET2 but
also private debts. This possibility augmented importantly in February 2012,
when the ECB allowed national central bank on their own risk to determine
eligible collateral for central-bank loans.[3] Depending on the exact
collateral rules, a Spanish bank may now loan to a Spanish company to import
from Germany. The Spanish bank may take the loan to the importer as collateral
for a new loan from the Bank of Spain (of course, applying a haircut). In this
way, the private loan (in this case used for consumption), has been monetized.
As an effect there will be also TARGET2 debits for the Bank of Spain and
TARGET2 credits for the Bundesbank.
What Are the Risks Exactly for
a TARGET2 Credit Country Such as Germany?
If Greece leaves the euro, it
most probably will not pay its debits to ECB with gold or hard assets. The ECB
will suffer a loss, and through its capital contribution 27 percent of such a
loss falls on the Bundesbank. If more countries leave the euro, the loss is
correspondingly higher. In the opposite case of a German exit of the euro, the
Bundesbank will suffer important losses if the new German currency appreciates
as the Bundesbank's main assets are now TARGET2 credits denominated in euros.
Moreover, the remaining eurozone countries might resist paying for the TARGET2
credits.
But is the liquidation of
TARGET2 credits a real loss? If we take our initial example of the two
individuals with a clearing bank, the conclusion is straightforward. If B
defaults, the bank goes bankrupt and A loses his savings. The same happens in
the case of the Eurosystem. If the peripheral governments default, their banks
default, their national central banks default and the ECB goes bankrupt. The
Bundesbank then has a TARGET2 claim on the bankrupt ECB and goes bust too.
Commerzbank loses its claims on the Bundesbank (or is not refinanced anymore)
and defaults as well. Then the German saver is left with nothing but empty
hands. The purpose of the visible bailouts of peripheral countries such as
Greece is to maintain the illusion that no losses are to be suffered for savers
in Germany and other countries.
But can the ECB or the
Bundesbank really go bankrupt? Can they not always pay, just by printing more
money? It is true that the ECB can always pay its bills by producing money.
However, creating money does not take away the fact that the wealth is gone
when the periphery defaults. It is like B not paying with real goods because he
dies. A may receive new paper money from his bank, but this will not feed him
through retirement. Unfortunately, as long as the European periphery remains
uncompetitive relative to Germany, nothing will be produced to settle the
German TARGET2 credits. Most likely, their real value is gone forever. To think
that they will represent real wealth is an illusion that will be ended in one
of three possible ways. The first is the already-mentioned inflation when the
ECB just prints money to keep the system afloat.
Second, in the case of a
peripheral default, the quality of the assets of the ECB is impaired, its
capital consumed. The ECB loses options to reduce the quantity of money in
circulation and defend the value of the euro. The ECB simply has no good assets
to sell; they have evaporated. There is the danger that the confidence in the
currency evaporates also, first on international currency markets and later
internally. The value of the currency may collapse and the wealth illusion of
currency holders and savers ends.
Third, another alternative is
to recapitalize the ECB by transferring high-quality assets to it. The ECB can
then use these assets to maintain confidence in the currency and defend its
value. The recapitalization, of course, requires also an expropriation of
wealth holders in Germany and other countries. After default and inflation,
fiscal expropriation means an alternative end to the wealth illusion.
TARGET2, Eurobonds, European
Stability Mechanism: What Is the Difference?
Eurobonds are jointly issued
and guaranteed by all 17 eurozone members but have been very controversial. For
instance, Eurobonds have been vehemently resisted by the German government
until today. However, TARGET2 has not been resisted by the German government.
TARGET2 is just the reflection of a substitute bailout. When governments issue
bonds bought by their banks leading to a trade deficit, the result is a TARGET2
debit. The TARGET2 imbalances are just a sign of euros created in the periphery
used to pay for goods from abroad.
The European Stability
Mechanism (ESM) is another substitute for Eurobonds, as the ESM may grant loans
to struggling governments issuing bonds guaranteed collectively. The difference
between the three is merely of degree. There is more parliamentary control for
Eurobonds or the ESM. In the ESM, creditor countries have more control over
bailouts than with Eurobonds. Interest rates differences are also more
pronounced with the ESM than with Eurobonds. The ECB wants to shift the bailout
burden from TARGET2 to the ESM. Governments prefer to hide the losses on
taxpayers as long as possible and prefer the ECB to aliment deficits. However,
all three devices serve as bailout systems and form a transfer union.
Notes
[1] The best short
introduction and analysis of TARGET2 may be found in Stefan Homburg,
"Anmerkungen zum Target-2-Streit," Wirtschaftsdienst, volume 91,
numer 3 (2011): pp. 536–530. Our analysis and graphs follow Homburg's line of
argumentation closely.
[2] At least these rules
appear in the Federal Reserve accounting manual. It seems, though, as if the
Fed has suspended settlements ultimately. See Michiel Bijlsma and Jasper
Lukkezen "Target-2 of the ECB vs. Interdistrict Settlement Account of the
Federal Reserve" (2012).
[3] Jens Weidmann criticized
the change in collateral rules and demanded collateral for TARGET2 debits in
March 2012. However, only central banks and governments could provide good
collateral such as gold for TARGET2 debits. Most banks have no good collateral
left. Otherwise they would have used it to refinance themselves on the private
markets and not through the Eurosystem with its low collateral standards.
No comments:
Post a Comment