By Llewellyn H. Rockwell Jr
I'm sure that you have had this experience before, or something similar
to it. You are sitting at lunch in a nice restaurant or perhaps a hotel.
Waiters are coming and going. The food is fantastic. The conversation about all
things is going well. You talk about the weather, music, movies, health,
trivialities in the news, kids, and so on. But then the topic turns to
economics, and things change.
You are not the aggressive type so you don't proclaim the merits of the
free market immediately. You wait and let the others talk. Their biases against
business appear right away in the repetition of the media's latest calumny
against the market, such as that gas station owners are causing inflation by
jacking up prices to pad their pockets at our expense, or that Walmart is, of
course, the worst possible thing that can ever happen to a community.
You begin to offer a corrective, pointing out the other side. Then the
truth emerges in the form of a naïve if definitive announcement from one
person: "Well, I suppose I'm really a socialist at heart." Others nod
in agreement.
On one hand there is nothing to say, really. You are surrounded by the
blessings of capitalism. The buffet table, which you and your lunch partners
only had to walk into a building to find, has a greater variety of food at a
cheaper price than that which was available to any living person — king, lord,
duke, plutocrat, or pope — in almost all of the history of the world. Not even
50 years ago would this have been imaginable.
All of history has been defined by the struggle for food. And yet that
struggle has been abolished, not just for the rich but for everyone living in
developed economies. The ancients, peering into this scene, might have assumed
it to be Elysium. Medieval man conjured up such scenes only in visions of Utopia. Even in the late 19th century, the most
gilded palace of the richest industrialist required a vast staff and immense
trouble to come anywhere near approximating it.
We owe this scene to capitalism. To put it differently, we owe this
scene to centuries of capital accumulation at the hands of free people who have
put capital to work on behalf of economic innovations, at once competing with
others for profit and cooperating with millions upon millions of people in an
ever-expanding global network of the division of labor. The savings,
investments, risks, and work of hundreds of years and uncountable numbers of
free people have gone into making this scene possible, thanks to the
ever-remarkable capacity for a society developing under conditions of liberty
to achieve the highest aspirations of the society's members.
And yet, sitting on the other side of the table are well-educated people who imagine that the way to end the world's woes is through socialism. Now, people's definitions of socialism differ, and these persons would probably be quick to say that they do not mean the Soviet Union or anything like that. That was socialism in name only, I would be told. And yet, if socialism does mean anything at all today, it imagines that there can be some social improvement resulting from the political movement to take capital out of private hands and put it into the hands of the state. Other tendencies of socialism include the desire to see labor organized along class lines and given some sort of coercive power over how their employers' property is used. It might be as simple as the desire to put a cap on the salaries of CEOs, or it could be as extreme as the desire to abolish all private property, money, and even marriage.
Whatever the specifics of the case in question, socialism always means
overriding the free decisions of individuals and replacing that capacity for
decision making with an overarching plan by the state. Taken far enough, this
mode of thought won't just spell an end to opulent lunches. It will mean the end
of what we all know as civilization itself. It would plunge us back to a
primitive state of existence, living off hunting and gathering in a world with
little art, music, leisure, or charity. Nor is any form of socialism capable of
providing for the needs of the world's 6 billion people, so the population
would shrink dramatically and quickly and in a manner that would make every
human horror ever known seem mild by comparison. Nor is it possible to divorce
socialism from totalitarianism, because if you are serious about ending private
ownership of the means of production, you have to be serious about ending
freedom and creativity too. You will have to make the whole of society, or what
is left of it, into a prison.
"Socialism always means overriding the free decisions of
individuals and replacing that capacity for decision making with an overarching
plan by the state."
In short, the wish for socialism is a wish for unparalleled human evil.
If we really understood this, no one would express casual support for it in
polite company. It would be like saying, you know, there is really something to
be said for malaria and typhoid and dropping atom bombs on millions of
innocents.
Do the people sitting across the table really wish for this? Certainly
not. So what has gone wrong here? Why can these people not see what is obvious?
Why can't people sitting amidst market-created plenty, enjoying all the fruits
of capitalism every minute of life, see the merit of the market but rather wish
for something that is a proven disaster?
What we have here is a failure of understanding. That is to say, a
failure to connect causes with effects. This is a wholly abstract idea.
Knowledge of cause and effect does not come to us by merely looking around a
room, living in a certain kind of society, or observing statistics. You can
study roomfuls of data, read a thousand treatises on history, or plot
international GDP figures on a graph for a living, and yet the truth about
cause and effect can still be evasive. You still might miss the point that it
is capitalism that gives rise to prosperity and freedom. You might still be
tempted by the notion of socialism as savior.
Let me take you back to the years 1989 and 1990. These were the years
that most of us remember as the time when socialism collapsed in Eastern Europe
and Russia. Events of that time flew in the face of all predictions on the
Right that these were permanent regimes that would never change unless they
were bombed back to the Stone Age. On the Left, it was widely believed, even in
those times, that these societies were actually doing quite well and would
eventually pass the United States and Western Europe in prosperity, and, by
some measures, that they were already better off than us.
And yet it collapsed. Even the Berlin Wall, that symbol of oppression
and slavery, was torn down by the people themselves. It was not only glorious
to see socialism collapse. It was thrilling, from a libertarian point of view,
to see how states themselves can dissolve. They may have all the guns and all
the power, and the people have none of those, and yet, when the people
themselves decide that they will no longer be governed, the state has few
options left. It eventually collapses amid a society-wide refusal to believe
its lies any longer.
When these closed societies suddenly became open, what did we see? We
saw lands that time forgot. The technology was backwards and broken. The food
was scarce and disgusting. The medical care was abysmal. The people were
unhealthy. Property was polluted.
It was also striking to see what had happened to the culture under
socialism. Many generations had been raised under a system built on power and
lies, and so the cultural infrastructure that we take for granted was not
secure. Such notions as trust, promise, truth, honesty, and planning for the
future — all pillars of commercial culture — had become distorted and confused
by the ubiquity and persistence of the statist curse.
Why am I going through these details about this period, which most of
you surely do remember? Simply to say this: most people did not see what you
saw. You saw the failure of socialism. This is what I saw. This is what
Rothbard saw. This is what anyone who had been exposed to the teachings of
economics — to the elementary rules concerning cause and effect in society —
saw.
But this is not what the ideological Left saw. The headlines in the
socialist publications themselves proclaimed the death of undemocratic
Stalinism and looked forward to the creation of a new democratic socialism in
these countries.
As for regular people neither attached to the socialist idea nor
educated in economics, it might have appeared as nothing more than a glorious
vanquishing of America's foreign-policy enemies. We built more bombs than they
did, so they finally gave in — the way a kid says "uncle" on a
playground. Maybe some saw it as a victory of the US Constitution over weird
and foreign systems of despotism. Or perhaps it was a victory for the cause of
something like free speech over censorship, or the triumph of ballots over
bullets.
Now, if the proper lessons of the collapse had been conveyed, we would
have seen the error of all forms of government planning. We would have seen
that a voluntary society will outperform a coerced one anytime. We might see
how ultimately artificial and fragile are all systems of statism compared to
the robust permanence of a society built on free exchange and capitalist
ownership. And there is another point: the militarism of the Cold War had only
ended up prolonging the period of socialism by providing these evil governments
the chance to stimulate unfortunate nationalist impulses that distracted their
domestic populations from the real problem. It was not the Cold War that killed
socialism; rather, once the Cold War had exhausted itself, these governments
collapsed of their own weight from internal rather than external pressure.
In short, if the world had drawn the correct lessons from these events,
there would be no more need for economic education and no more need even for
the bulk of what the Mises Institute does. In one great moment of history, the
contest between capitalism and central planning would have been decided for all
time.
I must say that it was more of a shock to my colleagues and me than it
should have been, that the essential economic message was lost on most people.
Indeed, it made very little difference in the political spectrum at all. The
contest between capitalism and central planning continued as it always had, and
even intensified here at home. The socialists among us, if they experienced any
setback at all, bounded right back, strong as ever, if not more so.
If you doubt it, consider that it only took a few months for these
groups to start kvetching about the horrible onslaught that was being wrought
by the unleashing of capitalism in Eastern Europe, Russia, and China. We began
hearing complaints about the rise of a hideous consumerism in these countries,
about the exploitation of workers at the hands of capitalists, about the rise
of the garish super rich. Piles and piles of news stories appeared about the
sad plight of unemployed state workers, who, though loyal to the principles of
socialism their entire lives, were now being turned out onto the streets to
fend for themselves.
Not even an event as spectacular as the spontaneous meltdown of a
superpower and all its client states was enough to impart the message of
economic freedom. And the truth is that it was not necessary. The whole of our
world is covered with lessons about the merit of economic liberty over central
planning. Our everyday lives are dominated by the glorious products of the
market, which we all gladly take for granted. We can open up our web browsers
and tour an electronic civilization that the market created, and note that
government never did anything useful at all by comparison.
We are also inundated daily by the failures of the state. We complain
constantly that the educational system is broken, that the medical sector is
oddly distorted, that the post office is unaccountable, that the police abuse
their power, that the politicians have lied to us, that tax dollars are stolen,
that whatever bureaucracy we have to deal with is inhumanly unresponsive. We
note all this. But far fewer are somehow able to connect the dots and see the
myriad ways in which daily life confirms that the market radicals like Mises,
Hayek, Hazlitt, and Rothbard were correct in their judgments.
What's more, this is not a new phenomenon that we can observe in our
lifetimes only. We can look at any country in any period and note that every
bit of wealth ever created in the history of mankind has been generated through
some kind of market activity, and never by governments. Free people create;
states destroy. It was true in the ancient world. It was true in the first
millennium after Christ. It was true in the Middle Ages and the Renaissance.
And with the birth of complex structures of production and the increasing
division of labor in those years, we see how the accumulation of capital led to
what might be called a productive miracle. The world's population soared. We
saw the creation of the middle class. We saw the poor improve their plight and
change their own class identification.
The empirical truth has never been hard to come by. What matters are the
theoretical eyes that see. This is what dictates the lesson we draw from
events. Marx and Bastiat were writing at the same time. The former said
capitalism was creating a calamity and that abolition of ownership was the
solution. Bastiat saw that statism was creating a calamity and that the
abolition of state plunder was the solution. What was the difference between
them? They saw the same facts, but they saw them in very different ways. They
had a different perception of cause and effect.
I suggest to you that there is an important lesson here as regards the
methodology of the social sciences, as well as an agenda and strategy for the
future. Concerning method, we need to recognize that Mises was precisely right
concerning the relationship between facts and economic truth. If we have a
solid theory in mind, the facts on the ground provide excellent illustrative
material. They inform us about the application of theory in the world in which
we live. They provided excellent anecdotes and revealing stories of how
economic theory is confirmed in practice. But absent that theory of economics,
facts alone are nothing but facts. They do not convey any information about
cause and effect, and they do not point a way forward.
Think of it this way. Let's say you have a bag of marbles that is turned
upside down on the ground. Ask two people their impressions. The first one
understands what numbers mean, what shapes mean, and what colors mean. This
person can give a detailed account of what he sees: how many marbles, what
kinds, how big they are, and this person can explain what he sees in different
ways potentially for hours. But now consider the second person, who, we can
suppose, has absolutely no understanding of numbers, not even that they exist
as abstract ideas. This person has no comprehension of either shape or color.
He sees the same scene as the other person but cannot provide anything like an
explanation of any patterns. He has very little to say. All he sees is a series
of random objects.
Both these people see the same facts. But they understand them in very
different ways, owing to the abstract notions of meaning that they carry in
their minds. This is why positivism as pure science, a method of assembling a
potentially infinite series of data points, is a fruitless undertaking. Data
points on their own convey no theory, suggest no conclusions, and offer no
truths. To arrive at truth requires the most important step that we as human
beings can ever take: thinking. Through this thinking, and with good teaching
and reading, we can put together a coherent theoretical apparatus that helps
us understand.
Now, we have a hard time conjuring up in our minds the likes of a man
who has no comprehension of numbers, colors, or shapes. And yet I suggest to
you that this is precisely what we are facing when we encounter a person who
has never thought about economic theory and never studied the implications of
the science at all. The facts of the world look quite random to this person. He
sees two societies next to each other, one free and prosperous and the other
unfree and poor. He looks at this and concludes nothing important about
economic systems because he has never thought hard about the relationship
between economic systems and prosperity and freedom.
He merely accepts the existence of wealth in one place and poverty in
the other as a given, the same way the socialists at a lunch table assumed that
the luxurious surroundings and food just happened to be there. Perhaps they
will reach for an explanation of some sort, but absent economic education, it
is not likely to be the correct one.
Equally as dangerous as having no theory is having a bad theory that is
assembled not by means of logic but by an incorrect view of cause and effect.
This is the case with notions such as the Phillips Curve, which posits a tradeoff relationship
between inflation and unemployment. The idea is that you can drive unemployment
down very low if you are willing to tolerate high inflation; or it can work the
other way around: you can stabilize prices provided you are willing to put up
with high unemployment.
Now, of course this makes no sense on the microeconomic level. When
inflation is soaring, businesses don't suddenly say, hey, let's hire a bunch of
new people! Nor do they say, you know, the prices we pay for inventory have not
gone up or have fallen. Let's fire some workers!
This much is true about macroeconomics: It is commonly treated like a
subject completely devoid of any connection to microeconomics or even human
decision making. It is as if we enter into a video game featuring fearsome
creatures called Aggregates that battle it out to the death. So you have one
creature called Unemployment, one called Inflation, one called Capital, one
called Labor, and so on until you can construct a fun game that is sheer
fantasy.
Another example of this came to me just the other day. A recent study
claimed that labor unions increase the productivity of firms. How did the
researchers discern this? They found that unionized companies tend to be larger
with more overall output than nonunionized companies. Well, let's think about
this. Is it likely that if you close a labor pool to all competition, give that
restrictive labor pool the right to use violence to enforce its cartel, permit
that cartel to extract higher-than-market wages from the company and set its
own terms concerning work rules and vacations and benefits — is it likely that
this will be good for the company in the long run? You have to take leave of
your senses to believe this.
In fact, what we have here is a simple mix-up of cause and effect.
Bigger companies tend to be more likely to attract a kind of unpreventable
unionization than smaller ones. The unions target them, with federal aid. It is
no more or less complicated than that. It is for the same reason that developed
economies have larger welfare states. The parasites prefer bigger hosts; that's
all. We would be making a big mistake to assume that the welfare state causes
the developed economy. That would be as much a fallacy as to believe that
wearing $2,000 suits causes people to become rich.
I'm convinced that Mises was right: the most important step economists
or economic institutions can take is in the direction of public education in
economic logic.
There is another important factor here. The state thrives on an
economically ignorant public. This is the only way it can get away with blaming
inflation or recession on consumers, or claiming that the government's fiscal
problems are due to our paying too little in taxes. It is economic ignorance
that permits the regulatory agencies to claim that they are protecting us as
versus denying us choice. It is only by keeping us all in the dark that it can
continue to start war after war — violating rights abroad and smashing
liberties at home — in the name of spreading freedom.
There is only one force that can put an end to the successes of the
state, and that is an economically and morally informed public. Otherwise, the
state can continue to spread its malicious and destructive policies.
Do you remember the first time that you began to grasp economic
fundamentals? It is a very exciting time. It is as if people with poor eyesight
have put on glasses for the first time. It can consume us for weeks, months,
and years. We read a book like Economics in One Lesson and pore over the pages of Human Action, and for the first time we realize that
so much of what other people take for granted is not true, and that there are
exciting truths about the world that desperately need to be spread.
To consider just one example, look at the concept of inflation. For most
people, it is seen the way primitive societies might see the onset of a
disease. It is something that sweeps through to cause every kind of wreckage.
The damage is obvious enough, but the source is not. Everyone blames everyone
else, and no solution seems to work. But once you understand economics, you
begin to see that the value of the money is more directly related to its
quantity, and that only one institution possesses the power to create money out
of thin air without limit: the government-connected central bank.
Economics causes us to broaden our minds to look at the commerce of
society from many different points of view. Instead of just looking at events
and phenomena from the perspective of a single consumer or producer, we begin
to see the interests of all consumers and all producers. Instead of thinking only
about the short-run effects of certain policies, we think about the long run,
and the spin-off effects of certain government policies. This is the essence of
Hazlitt's first lesson in his famed book.
By the way, let me interrupt here to make an exciting announcement. This
book was written more than 60 years ago, and it remains the most powerful first
book on economics anyone can read. Even if it is the last book on economics you
read, it will stick with you for a lifetime.
It is a hugely important tool, and though I'm glad that it has stayed in
print, I've not been happy with the edition that has long been distributed. We
had long hoped for a hardback version of this amazing classic to make available
at a very low price. Now we have it.
For a person who has read in economics, and absorbed its essential
lessons, the world around us becomes vivid and clear, and certain moral
imperatives strike us. We know now that commerce deserves defense. We see
entrepreneurs as great heroes. We sympathize with the plight of producers. We
see unions not as defenders of rights but as privileged cartels that exclude
people who need work. We see regulations not as consumer protection but rather
as cost-raising rackets lobbied for by some producers to hurt other producers.
We see antitrust not as a safeguard against corporate excess but as a bludgeon
used by big players against smarter competitors.
In short, economics helps us see the world as it is. And its
contribution lies not in the direction of the assembly of ever more facts, but
in helping those facts fit a coherent theory of the world. And here we see the
essence of our job at the Mises Institute. It is to educate and instill a
systematic method for understanding the world as it is. Our battleground is not
the courts, nor the election polls, nor the presidency, nor the legislature,
and certainly not the wicked arena of lobbying and political payoffs. Our
battleground concerns a domain of existence that is more powerful in the long
run. It concerns the ideas that individuals hold about how the world works.
As we get older and see ever more young generations coming up behind us,
we are often struck by the great truth that knowledge in this world is not
cumulative over time. What one generation has learned and absorbed is not somehow
passed on to the next one through genetics or osmosis. Each generation must be
taught anew. Economic theory, I'm sorry to report, is not written on our
hearts. It was a long time in the process of being discovered. But now that we
know, it must be passed on — and in this way, it is like the ability to read,
or to understand great literature. It is the obligation of our generation to
teach the next generation.
"If the world had drawn the correct lessons from these events, there would be no more need for economic education and no more need even for the bulk of what the Mises Institute does."
And we are not merely talking here of knowledge for knowledge's sake.
What is at stake is our prosperity. It is our standard of living. It is the
well-being of our children and all of society. It is freedom and the
flourishing of civilization that stand in the balance. Whether we grow and
thrive and create and flourish, or wither and die and lose all that we have
inherited, ultimately depends on these abstract ideas we hold concerning cause
and effect in society. These ideas do not usually come to us by pure
observation. They must be taught and explained.
But who or what will teach and explain them? And not only to teach but to expand the base of knowledge,
to make new discoveries, to broaden the reach of the literature, and to add
ever more abundantly to the corpus of freedom. We need to expand its proponents
in all walks of life, not only in academia but in all sectors of society. This
is an ambitious agenda, one that Mises himself charged his descendents with.
No comments:
Post a Comment