Large German trade surpluses
are ingrained in the Eurozone’s structure, but private sector mechanisms for
dealing with the corresponding capital account deficit are broken. The
unavoidable result has been large official capital account deficits by Germany
(the bailouts) and the Eurosystem (Target2 balances). This column proposes the
creation of a Germany sovereign wealth fund that would restart the private
recycling of Germany’s excess savings – eventually cleaning out the Target2
imbalances and depreciating the euro in the process.
Since the early 1950s, German
savings have tended to exceed investment with the inevitable result that that
Germans have, on net, been investing in foreign assets.
·
Most of these excess savings have been intermediated by the domestic
banking system.
The banks have difficulties
investing German surpluses abroad given that they finance themselves through
deposits in the national currency and thus cannot take exchange rate risk. The
resulting exchange rate adjusted tended to keep the surplus under 1% to 2% of
GDP most of the time.
·
With the advent of the euro, exchange rate risk within the Eurozone
disappeared and German surpluses vis-à-vis EZ partner countries could and did
become much larger.
·
Large surpluses seem to have become structurally ingrained at a whopping 6%
of GDP; that is more than a quarter of national savings.
As the sovereign debt and
banking crisis took the Eurozone in its grip, the appetite of German private
investors for Eurozone public and private debt diminished sharply. Investment
outside the Eurozone was not an alternative given that a large number of German
savings are still intermediated by banks and must thus remain denominated in
euro.
To avoid a breakdown of the financial system, the public sector has now had to intermediate German savings surpluses. This happened in two ways:
To avoid a breakdown of the financial system, the public sector has now had to intermediate German savings surpluses. This happened in two ways:
·
Limited loans by the German government (and other governments of countries
with large external surpluses) to Greece directly and via the euro rescue fund
(EFSF, soon the ESM) to the three countries with a ‘Troika’ programme; and
·
The Eurosystem acting as the main intermediary of savings from surplus to
deficit countries via Target2 balances.
Its role is reflected in the
imbalances within the interbank payment system Target 2, which broadly
correspond to EZ countries’ cumulated current account positions since the
introduction of the euro; see the illustration below. (For a detailed analysis
of the Target2 balances, see Sinn & Wollmershäuser, 2012).
Figure 1. Target2 balances and excess
savings
The
Eurosystem’s response
The Eurosystem’s role in
intermediating large private-sector savings surpluses should not be regarded as
abnormal. On the contrary, there are very few examples of countries with
consistently large external surpluses being intermediated for long periods exclusively
by the private sector.
In most countries running
persistent current account surpluses (say, above 3% of GDP for more than five
years), the government or the central bank has accumulated large foreign assets
either through a sovereign wealth fund or through foreign exchange
intervention.
·
In raw-material-exporting countries, where the external surplus is
generated by the royalties that go to the government, the sovereign wealth fund
is the natural choice.
Saudi Arabia and Norway
provide the classic examples of natural resources-based surpluses intermediated
by the public sector through a sovereign wealth fund.
·
In countries where the external surplus arises from excess savings in the
private sector, foreign exchange intervention is the usual route to absorb the
risk arising from the large net foreign asset position the private sector is
accumulating.
Switzerland and Japan can
illustrate the tendency of countries with structural private-sector surpluses
to rely on the central bank.
The
Eurosystem solution is inefficient
If there is indeed a role for
the public sector to intermediate very large surplus savings, the question
arises: is this intermediation done in an efficient way? From a German
perspective, intermediation by the Eurosystem is, on balance, inefficient.
·
On the one hand, any credit risk incurred by the Bundesbank through the
accumulation of Target2 claims against the ECB is shared with other EZ
countries through the distribution of any losses according to the share of countries
in the capital of the ECB.
·
On the other hand, the Target claims represent a portfolio that is,
geographically and across asset classes, very concentrated.
Target2 claims are in the end
only backed by the securities of banks in deficit countries delivered as
collateral for ECB credits under the various credit facilities. A large part of
these securities is probably of dubious quality, even if they often carry a
government guarantee.
Target2 is inefficient from an
investors perspective. The ECB offers German banks, and hence indirectly the
country’s savers, at present a nominal interest rate of zero (which may even
move into negative territory in the future), and it demands only 75 bps on its
lending to banks in the Eurozone periphery.
·
A 'margin' of 75 bps seems totally insufficient to cover the risks taken in
the ECB’s operations.
Also, the zero nominal
interest rate offered by the ECB's deposit facility translates into a negative
real return for German savers of around 2% per annum under the ECB’s target
inflation rate. And it could be even less when German inflation rises above the
ECB’s target (as would seem necessary to allow internal real exchange rate
adjustment in the Eurozone).
Finally, the ECB (by its
nature as a central bank) is not able to offer German savers any longer-term
investment vehicles. This is a key drawback given the lack of long-term savings
vehicles available now because most German government debt has been absorbed by
foreign central banks (e.g. from Switzerland and China) and sovereign wealth
funds.
Setting
up a Sovereign Wealth Fund to kickstart private lending
An alternative to the present
system of intermediation of the German savings surplus, which would avoid the
aforementioned disadvantages, would be a German Sovereign Wealth Fund (DESWF).
·
A government agency would offer German savers a secure vehicle paying a
guaranteed positive minimum real interest rate, with a top-up when real
investment returns allowed.
·
The vehicle would invest the funds in a portfolio that is highly diversified
by geography and asset classes.
Positive real returns can be
expected in the long run based on positive real global growth.
·
With the DESWF channelling a significant part of German excess savings
outside the Eurozone, the euro would depreciate.
This would help crisis
countries to revive growth through exports, and to close their external
deficits so as to recoup their international credit-worthiness.
·
Target2 imbalances would gradually disappear and German claims abroad would
move from nominal claims on the ECB (with a zero interest rate) to diversified
real and nominal claims on various private and public foreign entities in a
variety of asset classes around the globe.
Investments into the German
sovereign wealth fund could be restricted to longer-term commitments, thereby
helping to achieve positive real returns through participation in global growth
and thus be equivalent to a funded old-age pension scheme as a supplement to
the existing German pay-as-you go scheme.
The
risks
The DESWF would of course
carry the investment risk, including the exchange rate risk, but its ability to
deploy large amounts of funds globally with a long-term investment horizon
would put it into a better position to handle these risks than individual
investors or private financial institutions (such as banks or insurance
companies). The latter either pass the exchange rate risk on to their customers
or, if they cannot do this, avoid it because of regulatory requirements or in
order to save equity capital that would be needed as risk buffer. For example,
German insurance companies, which manage of about €1,200 billion of mostly long
term assets (equivalent to about one half of German GDP) have invested only
about 5% of these funds outside the Eurozone.
Conclusion
Eventually, the enlargement of
cross-border capital flows and their concentration on Eurozone countries
brought about by the euro will have to be unwound. Only when these flows
reflect long-term viable investment opportunities will they no longer
constitute a danger for the stability of the euro.
This requires a shrinking of
current account deficits as well as surpluses of EZ countries. However, in view
of the structural savings surpluses of some EZ member countries, intra-area
current account adjustment alone will probably not be enough. What is also
required is a redirection of the current account surpluses to countries outside
the Eurozone. If the private sector is unable to do this because of its
reluctance to assume exchange rate risk, the public sector may have to help. In
any case, an increased demand for foreign assets will lower the exchange rate
of the euro, which will facilitate efforts by the deficit countries to overcome
recession by an expansion of exports.
One might of course object to
our proposal that it presents a typical 'Germanic' mercantilist view which
transfers the burden of adjustment to the rest of the world. But under the
current circumstances one has to choose the lesser evil: a strong euro combined
with ever-increasing internal tensions which threaten global financial
stability, or a weaker euro without the internal tensions. We believe that the
global economy will be better off under the second scenario.
No comments:
Post a Comment