By Anders Åslund
It has become increasingly
fashionable to talk about Europe without the euro. But this column points out
that in the last century Europe has seen the collapse of three multi-nation
currency zones: the Habsburg Empire, the Soviet Union, and Yugoslavia – and
they all ended with disastrous hyperinflation. The lesson for the Eurozone is
clear: avoid break up at almost any cost.
Articles on a possible breakup
of Eurozone either see it as a mere devaluation (Lachman 2010, Roubini 2011) or
reckon that its collapse would amount to a major economic disaster (Buiter
2011, Cliffe et al. 2010, Normand and Sandilya 2011). It seems the latter is
more likely. Large imbalances have accumulated between southern debtor
countries and northern creditor countries. Any capping of these balances would
disrupt the payments mechanism between the Eurozone countries and impede all
economic activity (Åslund 2012).
In the last century, Europe
saw the collapse of three multi-nation currency zones, the Habsburg Empire, the
Soviet Union, and Yugoslavia. They all ended in major disasters with
hyperinflation. In the Habsburg Empire, Austria and Hungary faced
hyperinflation. Yugoslavia experienced hyperinflation twice. In the former
Soviet Union, ten out of 15 republics had hyperinflation (e.g. Pasvolsky 1928,
Dornbusch 1992, Pleskovic and Sachs 1994, and Åslund 1995).
The output falls were horrendous and long lasting. The statistics are flimsy, but officially the average output fall in the former Soviet Union was 52%, and in the Baltics it amounted to 42% (Åslund 2007, 60). Five out of twelve post-Soviet countries – Ukraine, Moldova, Georgia, Kyrgyzstan, and Tajikistan – had not reached their 1990 GDP per capita levels in purchasing power parities by 2010. Similarly, out of seven Yugoslav successor states, at least Serbia and Montenegro, and probably Kosovo and Bosnia-Herzegovina, had not exceeded their 1990 GDP per capita levels in purchasing power parities two decades later (World Bank 2011). Arguably, Austria and Hungary did not recover from their hyperinflations in the early 1920s until the mid-1950s. Thus half the countries in a currency zone that broke up experienced hyperinflation and did not reach their prior GDP per capita in purchasing power parities until about a quarter of a century later.
The causes of these large
output falls were multiple: systemic change, competitive monetary emission
leading to hyperinflation, collapse of the payments system, exclusion from
international finance, trade disruption, and wars. Many economists disregard
the experiences of the former Soviet Union and Yugoslavia because both
countries also went through systemic changes. In an attempt to control for
systemic change we can compare the former Soviet Union with Romania and
Bulgaria, which also had highly distorted socialist economies and a similar
level of economic development as the Soviet Union. By such a comparison, the
total output cost because of the slow collapse of the ruble zone might be on
the order of 20% to 25%.
The critical issue is the
Eurozone payments system. Hans-Werner Sinn initiated a heated discussion about
unsettled Target2 clearing balances of the Eurozone in 2011 (e.g. Sinn 2012,
Whelan 2011, 2012). Before the current crisis, these balances more or less
offset each other or were settled through the private interbank market, which
has dried up. As a consequence, large positive Target2 balances have arisen
with the national central banks in the four northern Eurozone countries –
Germany, the Netherlands, Luxembourg, and Finland – and corresponding big
negative balances with eight countries – Italy, Spain, Ireland, Greece, France,
Portugal, Belgium, and Austria) (Sinn and Wollmershäuser 2012). The causes of
these balances are current-account deficits of the southern countries as well
as transfers of bank deposits from the south to the north. These balances
exceed €1 trillion, and Germany’s surplus alone corresponds to one-third of
Germany’s GDP.
Sinn (2011) has argued that
“the Eurozone payments system has been operating as a hidden bailout whereby
the Bundesbank has been lending money to the crisis-stricken Eurozone members
via the Target system.” He has alternatively proposed to cap the Target2
balances, settle them in hard assets, or transform them into short-term
Eurobonds. Karl Whelan (2011) and others oppose Sinn, arguing that the
Bundesbank has claims on the ECB system as a whole, not on individual national
central banks. Whelan points out that limiting a Target2 balance would amount
to cutting out a country from the euro system.
Legally, Whelan’s
interpretation is presumably correct, but since the Lisbon Treaty does not
contain any stipulations for the dissolution of the Eurozone, it is not evident
what law would apply to these balances if it does break up. If the ECB would
collapse in the breakup of the Eurozone, the main creditor would no longer
exist. Moreover, the southern countries would in all probability default on
their bonds in such an event, sharply reducing the value of any collateral held
as sovereign bonds.
The accumulation of large
uncleared balances of dubious character is symptomatic of a currency zone in
crisis. The former Soviet republics formally agreed to coordinate their issue
of credit, but they all failed to implement their agreement and competitive
credit issue ensued. All the other former Soviet republics had large
current-account deficits with Russia. Until the ruble zone collapsed in
September 1993 Russia financed them all. In 1992, Russia’s credits to the other
former Soviet republics amounted to 9.3% of its GDP. Formally, the gains of the
other states were enormous, ranging from 11% of GDP in Belarus and Moldova to
91% of GDP in Tajikistan (IMF 1994, p. 25). In reality, however, no country
benefited from this flow of money, which contributed to hyperinflation everywhere
(Åslund 1995). Similarly, Slovenia and Croatia had large current-account
surpluses in relation to Serbia, which responded by emitting far more credit
rather than paying in real terms, which in turn persuaded Slovenia and Croatia
to abandon the Yugoslav dinar (Pleskovich and Sachs 1994).
Domestically, post-Soviet
Russia had a clearing system that could not manage all the new payments, and
large arrears accumulated in the so-called Kartoteka II, where all payments
were registered in the order of their entry. The dominant Russian view was that
they should be financed with new monetary emission as indeed happened, which
resulted in high inflation. Uncleared payment balances anywhere may provoke
monetary emission.
Sinn has made an important
contribution by drawing attention to these large unsettled balances, but his
proposal to cap the national Target2 balances is very dangerous. The Russian
reformers set such ceilings on the credits from the Central Bank of Russia to
the other post-Soviet countries to limit Russia’s losses and break up the ruble
zone, as happened. No such limit on a clearing balance is permissible in a
currency zone. Nor is it permissible to ignore these balances, as Whelan seems
to suggest, because they can become real.
Sadly, both Sinn and Whelan’s
lines of argument are likely to contribute to the disruption of the Eurozone.
Sinn’s argument is a straightforward copy of the Russian breakup of the ruble
zone, while Whelan ignores the problem of uncleared Target2 balances.
If one country (Greece)
departs from the Eurozone or if its Target2 balances are capped, the current
slow bank run from the south will accelerate quickly and become a massive bank
run from most banks in southern Europe, and the banking system would stop
working. The Eurozone payments system would stop functioning because it is
centralized to the ECB. To re-establish a payments system is both politically
and technically difficult. In the former Soviet Union, it took three years to
do so. Currency controls would arise and a liquidity freeze would occur. If the
drachma were reintroduced in the midst of a severe financial crisis, its
exchange rate would plummet like a stone by probably 75%-80%. High inflation
would result and mass bankruptcies ensue because of currency mismatches. Output
would plunge and unemployment soar. Greece would experience a new default and
other countries would follow.
For all these reasons, Greece
or any other financially weak country is unlikely to depart from the Eurozone.
In the three hyperinflationary currency union collapses, it was small, wealthy
counties that left first: Czechoslovakia from the Habsburg Empire, Slovenia and
Croatia from Yugoslavia, and the three Baltic states from the former Soviet
Union. The countries that departed early and resolutely were most successful.
Hence, the main concern should be whether small, wealthy northern countries
want to abandon the Eurozone.
The conclusion is that the
Eurozone should be maintained at almost any cost. All the economic problems in
the current crisis can be resolved within the Eurozone. In order to maintain
the Eurozone, a Eurozone-wide clearing must be maintained in full. The Target2
balances should be resolved by reforms, not by capping national balances. The
only reasons for a breakup of the Eurozone would be that Eurozone governance
fails completely or that one nation decides to leave. If the breakup starts, it
would be better to agree on a complete and speedy dissolution into the old
national currencies.
References
Åslund, Anders (1995), How Russia Became a Market Economy, Washington:
Brookings Institution.
Åslund, Anders (2007), Building How Capitalism Was Built: The Transformation of Central
and Eastern Europe, Russia, and Central Asia, Cambridge University
Press.
Åslund, Anders (2012), “Why a
Breakup of the euro Area Must Be Avoided: Lessons from Previous Breakups”,
Policy Brief 12-20, Peterson Institute for International Economics, August.
Buiter, Willem (2011), “The
Terrible Consequences of a Eurozone Collapse”, Financial
Times, 8 December.
Cliffe, Mark et al. (2010),
“EMU Break-up: Quantifying the Unthinkable”, ING, Global Economics, 7 July.
Dornbusch, Rudiger (1992),
“Monetary Problems of Post Communism: Lessons from the End of the
Austro-Hungarian Empire”,Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv,
128(3):391-424.
International Monetary Fund
(1994), Economic Review: Financial Relations among Countries of the Former
Soviet Union, IMF.
Lachman, Desmond (2010), Can the Euro Survive?, Legatum Institute, December.
Normand, John, and Arindam
Sandilya (2011), “Answers to 10 Common Questions on EMU Breakup”, JP Morgan, 7
December.
Pasvolsky, Leo (1928), Economic Nationalism of the Danubian States, London:
George Allen & Unwin.
Pleskovic, Boris, and Jeffrey
D Sachs (1994), “Political Independence and Economic Reform in Slovenia”, in
Olivier Blanchard, Kenneth Froot, and Jeffrey D Sachs (eds.), The Transition in Eastern Europe, 1, National Bureau of
Economic Research, 191-220
Roubini, Nouriel (2011), “The
Eurozone Is Heading for Break-up”,Financial Times, 14
June.
Sinn, Hans-Werner (2011), “The
ECB’s Stealth Bailout”, VoxEU.org, 1
June.
Sinn, Hans-Werner (2012), “Fed Versus ECB: How TARGET Debts Can Be Repaid”, VoxEU.org, 10 March.
Sinn, Hans-Werner, and Timo
Wollmershäuser (2012), “Target Loans, Current Account Balances and Capital
Flows: The ECB’s Rescue Facility”,International Tax Public
Finance, 30 May.
Whelan, Karl (2011), “Professor Sinn Misses the Target”, VoxEU.org, 9 June.#
Whelan, Karl (2012), “Target2: Germany Has Bigger Things to Worry about”, VoxEU.org, 29 April.
World Bank (2011), World Development Indicators.
No comments:
Post a Comment