By Simon Johnson, Peter Boone
There is a common problem
underlying the economic troubles of Europe, Japan, and the US: the symbiotic
relationship between politicians who heed narrow interests and the growth of a
financial sector that has become increasingly opaque (Igan
and Mishra 2011). Bailouts have encouraged reckless behaviour in the financial sector,
which builds up further risks – and will lead to another round of shocks, collapses,
and bailouts.
This is what we have called
the ‘doomsday cycle’ (Boone and Johnson 2010). The cycle turned in 2007-8 and
was most dramatically manifest in the weeks and months that followed the fall
of Lehman Brothers, the collapse of Iceland’s banks and the botched ‘rescue’ of
the big three Irish financial institutions.
The consequences have included
sovereign debt restructuring by Greece, as well as continuing problems – and
lending programmes by the IMF and the EU – for Greece, Ireland, and Portugal.
Italy, Spain and other parts of the Eurozone remain under intense pressure.
Yet in some circles, there is
a sense that the countries of the Eurozone have put the worst of their problems
behind them. Following a string of summits, it is argued, Europe is now more
decisively on the path to a unified financial system backed by what will become
the substance of a fiscal union.
The doomsday cycle is indeed
turning – and problems are undoubtedly heading towards Japan and the US: the
current level of complacency among policymakers in those countries is alarming.
But the next turn of the global cycle looks likely to hit Europe again and
probably harder than before.
The continental European financial system is in big trouble: budgets are unsustainable and growth is nowhere on the horizon. The costs of bailouts are rising – and the coming scale of the problem is likely to undermine political support for the Eurozone itself.
The continental European financial system is in big trouble: budgets are unsustainable and growth is nowhere on the horizon. The costs of bailouts are rising – and the coming scale of the problem is likely to undermine political support for the Eurozone itself.
The
structure of the doomsday cycle
In the 1980s and 1990s, deep
economic crises occurred primarily in middle- and low-income countries that
were too small to have direct global effects. The crises we should fear today
are in relatively rich countries that are big enough to reduce growth around
the world.
The problem is that the modern
financial infrastructure makes it possible to borrow a great deal relative to
the size of an economy – and far more than is sustainable relative to growth
prospects. The expectation of bailouts has become built into the system, in
terms of government and central bank support. But this expectation is also
faulty because, at times, the claims on the system are more than can ultimately
be paid.
·
For politicians, this is a great opportunity.
It enables them to buy favour
and win re-election. The problems will become apparent, they calculate, on
someone else’s watch. So repeated bailouts have become the expectation not the
exception.
·
For bankers and financiers of all kinds, this is easy money and great
fortune – literally.
The complexity and scale of
modern finance make it easy to hide what is going on. The regulated financial
sector has little interest in speaking truth to authority; that would just
undercut their business. Banks that are ‘too big to fail’ benefit from giant,
hidden and very dangerous government subsidies. Yet despite repeated failures,
many top officials pretend that ‘the market’ or ‘smart regulators’ can take
care of this problem.
·
For the broader public, none of this is clear – until it is too late.
The issues are abstract and
lack the personal drama that grabs headlines. The policy community does not
understand the issues or becomes complicit in the schemes of politicians and
big banks. The true costs of bailouts are disguised and not broadly understood.
Millions of jobs are lost, lives ruined, fiscal balance sheets damaged – and
for what, exactly?
Over the past four centuries,
financial development has strongly supported economic development. The
market-based creation of new institutions and products encouraged savings by a
broad cross-section of society, allowing capital to flow into more productive
uses. But in recent decades, parts of our financial development have gone badly
off-track – becoming much more a ‘rent-seeking’ mechanism that draws support
from politicians because it facilitates irresponsible public policy.
·
The question is: Who will be hurt next by this structure?
There are three prominent
candidates: Japan, the US, and the Eurozone.
Japan’s
long march to collapse
Figure 1 shows the path of
Japan’s ratio of debt to GDP over the last 30 years, including IMF forecasts to
2016.
·
Japan has a rapidly ageing population.
The average Japanese woman
today has 1.39 children, far fewer than is needed to replace the elderly. This
means that the total population is set to decline by 26% by 2050. Having peaked
in the mid-1990s, the country’s working age population will decline by a
staggering 40% between 1995 and 2050. Naturally, many of the ageing Japanese have
been saving for their retirement for decades. They deposit those funds in
banks, buy government bonds, hold cash savings or buy Japanese equities.
·
Japan’s growth is slowing.
With an ageing population and
slower growth, the broad outlines of responsible policy are straightforward.
Japan should become a big investor in countries with younger populations,
providing the capital investment needed to generate growth. Those countries can
then return the savings to the Japanese as they retire. Singapore’s government
does just that via one of the world’s largest investment funds.
Instead, for the last two
decades, Japan’s government has been running large deficits, borrowing and then
spending the savings of the young. When the elderly finally demand their
savings back in the form of pensions, the government will need to reduce its
budget deficit of 8% of GDP and start running a sizeable budget surplus. Unless
there is a sudden burst of romance and fertility, there will be far fewer
Japanese taxpayers in the future to pay this debt.
The government has not been
willing to raise taxes in a timely manner to match its spending. The latest
agreement is for a modest (5%) increase in the retail sales tax, which would
only be fully implemented in 2015. Why would it do so in the future when the
burden on the remaining workers will need to be ever larger?
Japan is saved from immediate
pressure by the fact that about 95% of its government debt is held by domestic
residents. As long as these investors are satisfied with very low – or perhaps
negative – real rates, this situation can continue.
But sooner or later, Japan’s
dreadful fiscal mathematics will catch up with the government. There is no sign
yet of a broad loss of confidence, but major shifts in market sentiment are not
typically signalled in advance.
America’s
reckless private finance
In the US, the symptoms are
different. Figure 2 illustrates the US version of the doomsday cycle: the rise
of total credit as a fraction of national income. Major players in the
financial system have become too big to be allowed to fail – and consequently
receive large subsidies.
Figure 2
The latest crisis has led to the largest monetary and fiscal bailouts on record. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that the final fiscal impact of the crisis of 2007-8 will end up increasing debt relative to GDP by about 50 percentage points. This is the second largest debt shock in US history; measured in this way, only the Second World War cost more. (For more detail, see Johnson and Kwak 2012.)
The latest crisis has led to the largest monetary and fiscal bailouts on record. The Congressional Budget Office estimates that the final fiscal impact of the crisis of 2007-8 will end up increasing debt relative to GDP by about 50 percentage points. This is the second largest debt shock in US history; measured in this way, only the Second World War cost more. (For more detail, see Johnson and Kwak 2012.)
The alliance that leads to
unsustainable finance here is simple: the US financial system earns large
‘rents’ (excess returns to labour and capital) from the implicit subsidies
offered by taxpayers. These rents finance a massive system of lobbyists and
campaign donations that ensures ‘pro-bailout’ politicians win elections
regularly.
Each time the US has a crisis,
politicians and technocrats admit their errors and buttress regulators to
ensure that ‘it never happens again’. Yet still it happens, again and again. We
are now on our third round of the so-called Basel international rules for
banks, with the architects of each new reform admonishing the previous
architects for their mistakes. There’s no doubt that the US will someday soon
be correcting Basel 3 and moving on to Basel 4, 5, 6 and more.
The problem that the country
faces is that with each crisis, the financial risks are getting larger. If
continued in this manner, bailing out the system will eventually be
unaffordable. When the US finally runs out of enough savers to buy the bonds
needed to bail out the system, it will suffer the ultimate collapse. (For more
detail, see Schularick and Taylor 2012.)
Roughly half of all US federal
debt is currently held by non-residents. So US fiscal policy remains viable
only as long as the dollar is seen as the ultimate safe haven for investors.
But what is the competition? Japan is not appealing today as a haven and it is
unlikely to become more appealing in the near term. A great deal of the
prospects for the US budget and growth therefore rest on what happens in the
Eurozone.
The
Eurozone: Flawed dreams
There is no sign that the
Eurozone will emerge from crisis any time soon.
The incentive structure of the
Eurozone ensured that each country’s financial sector clamoured to join it. The
key feature that made it so attractive was the liquidity window at the ECB.
For smaller countries, the ECB
is a modern day Rumpelstiltskin. Rather than spinning straw into gold, the ECB
converts unattractive government and bank-issued securities into highly liquid
‘collateral’ that can be readily swapped for cash from the ECB. This feature
instantly made sovereign and bank bonds very attractive debt instruments.
Knowing that the borrowers had essentially unlimited access to liquidity from
the ECB, investors became willing lenders at low interest rates to all banks in
the Eurozone.
Given such attractive
features, it is easy to understand why 17 countries mastered the political
debate to join the Eurozone. It is also easy to understand how the system got
abused and why it will be so difficult ever to make it ‘safe’. If the Japanese
can’t control their public finances and if the US can’t control its
too-big-to-fail banks, the added complexity of merging 17 regulators and 17
national governments into a system where someone else can be made responsible
for bailing out the intransigents seems a financial and regulatory nightmare.
Such a system is sure to be
crisis-prone. The Federal Reserve and the US federal government’s attempt to
provide bailouts when there is trouble in the US. But in Europe, the bailouts
are only partial. No country has a ‘lender of last resort’ like the Federal
Reserve or the Bank of Japan – so markets are now learning that large risk
premia are needed to reflect default risk in troubled countries.
Flexible exchange rates would
undoubtedly make it easier to manage these crises. Devaluations instantly
reduce wages and raise countries’ competitiveness. If Greece had managed a
large devaluation, it could probably have avoided much of the unemployment and
social turmoil we see today. Instead, each troubled country in Europe now
suffers when having to force down wages and prices during adjustment.
This system poses great
dangers to global financial stability. The Eurozone faces myriad problems,
including insufficient bank capital, high levels of private and public debt,
and the chronic inability of some member countries to grow.
It is now common to hear
policymakers blackmailing populations: unless the Eurozone survives, tragedy
will result. And it is true that tragedy will result; we only need to look at
the rise of complex derivatives and the dangers they pose were the Eurozone to
dismantle. (For a broader discussion of Europe’s problems, see Boone and
Johnson 2011 and 2012.)
Figure 3 illustrates the
growth of euro-denominated interest rate derivatives, the notional value of
which now totals more than 10 times the GDP of the Eurozone. Regulators
commonly use net figures when they consider ultimate risk for banks and this
makes sense under the usual circumstances of bankruptcy. But when a currency
area breaks up, the practice of netting off contracts needs to change
dramatically and banks will be facing far more risks than regulators and risk
officers currently report.
Figure 3
For example, if a German bank
has a contract with a French bank and an opposite identical contract with a
German pension fund, it can net those two contracts and report the ultimate
risk as zero. (Of course there is counterparty risk, but under standard
agreements, derivatives are cleared instantly at liquidation so the
counterparty risks can be netted).
But if investors start to
believe that there will be new currencies in each country, then the two
contracts in this example are no longer offsetting so they must not be netted.
It is reasonable to think that after any demise of the euro, the contracts
between two German counterparties will be converted into deutsche marks, while
contracts with international partners will be disputed or maintained in a euro
proxy.
As a result, risk officers at
banks should understand that if the Eurozone breaks up, all banks in Europe
face enormous and unaccountable currency risk. Each of their ‘euro’ assets and
liabilities needs to be examined to understand into which currency it would be
converted. (For more discussion on redenomination issues, see Nordvig and
Firoozye 2012.)
The
threat of future crises
The tragedy of the Eurozone
appears unavoidable, but it reflects far greater risks that will spread to
Japan, the US, and other advanced economies.
Through our financial systems, we have created enormous, complex financial structures that can inflict tragic consequences with failure and yet are inherently difficult to regulate and control. We are at the behest of our politicians and financial sectors to prevent them from creating dangers. Yet around the world, our political and financial systems have aligned to build these dangers rather than suppress them.
Through our financial systems, we have created enormous, complex financial structures that can inflict tragic consequences with failure and yet are inherently difficult to regulate and control. We are at the behest of our politicians and financial sectors to prevent them from creating dangers. Yet around the world, our political and financial systems have aligned to build these dangers rather than suppress them.
The continuing crisis in the
Eurozone merely buys times for Japan and the US. Investors are seeking refuge
in these two countries only because the dangers are most imminent in the
Eurozone. Will these countries take this time to fix their underlying fiscal
and financial problems? That seems unlikely.
The lesson from all these
troubles is clear: the relatively recent rise of the institutions of complex
financial markets, around the world, has permitted the growth of large,
unsustainable finance. We rely on our political systems to check these dangers,
but instead the politicians naturally develop symbiotic relationships that
encourage irresponsible growth.
The nature of ‘irresponsible
growth’ is different in each country and region – but it is similarly
unsustainable and it is still growing. There are more crises to come and they
are likely to be worse than the last one.
Editor’s note: this piece
first appeared in CentrePiece magazine (Centre for Economic Performance, LSE).
References
Boone, Peter and Simon Johnson
(2010), “The Doomsday Cycle”, CentrePiece, 14:3.
Peter Boone and Simon Johnson (2011), “Europe on the Brink”, Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Boone, Peter and Simon Johnson (2012), “The European Crisis Deepens”, Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Igan, Deniz and Prachi Mishra (2011), “Three's company: Wall Street, Capitol Hill, and K Street”, VoxEU.org, 11 August.
Nordvig, Jens and Nick Firoozye (2012), “Planning for an Orderly Break-up of the European Monetary Union”, submission to the Wolfson Economics Prize 2012, Nomura Securities.
Johnson, Simon and James Kwak (2012), White House Burning: The Founding Fathers, Our National Debt and Why It Matters To You, Pantheon.
Schularick, Moritz and Alan Taylor (2012), “Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870-2008”, American Economic Review, 102(2):1029-1061.
Peter Boone and Simon Johnson (2011), “Europe on the Brink”, Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Boone, Peter and Simon Johnson (2012), “The European Crisis Deepens”, Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Igan, Deniz and Prachi Mishra (2011), “Three's company: Wall Street, Capitol Hill, and K Street”, VoxEU.org, 11 August.
Nordvig, Jens and Nick Firoozye (2012), “Planning for an Orderly Break-up of the European Monetary Union”, submission to the Wolfson Economics Prize 2012, Nomura Securities.
Johnson, Simon and James Kwak (2012), White House Burning: The Founding Fathers, Our National Debt and Why It Matters To You, Pantheon.
Schularick, Moritz and Alan Taylor (2012), “Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870-2008”, American Economic Review, 102(2):1029-1061.
No comments:
Post a Comment