by YUVAL LEVIN
It is becoming increasingly
clear that we in America are living through a period of transition. One chapter
of our national life is closing, and another is about to begin. We can sense
this in the tense volatility of our electoral politics, as dramatic
"change elections" follow closely upon one another. We can feel it in
the unseemly mood of decline that has infected our public life — leaving our
usually cheerful nation fretful about global competition and unsure if the next
generation will be able to live as well as the present one. Perhaps above all,
we can discern it in an overwhelming sense of exhaustion emanating from many of
our public institutions — our creaking mid-century transportation
infrastructure, our overburdened regulatory agencies struggling to keep pace
with a dynamic economy, our massive entitlement system edging toward
insolvency.
But these are mostly symptoms of our mounting unease.
The most significant cause runs deeper. We have the feeling
that profound and unsettling change is afoot because the vision that has
dominated our political imagination for a century — the vision of the
social-democratic welfare state — is drained and growing bankrupt, and it is not
yet clear just what will take its place.
That vision was an answer to a question America must still confront: How shall we balance the competing aspirations of our society — aspirations to both wealth and virtue, dynamism and compassion? How can we fulfill our simultaneous desires to race ahead yet leave no one behind? The answer offered by the social-democratic ideal was a technocratic welfare state that would balance these aspirations through all-encompassing programs of social insurance. We would retain a private economy, but it would be carefully managed in order to curb its ill effects, and a large portion of its output would be used by the government to address large social problems, lessen inequality, and thus also build greater social solidarity.
That vision was an answer to a question America must still confront: How shall we balance the competing aspirations of our society — aspirations to both wealth and virtue, dynamism and compassion? How can we fulfill our simultaneous desires to race ahead yet leave no one behind? The answer offered by the social-democratic ideal was a technocratic welfare state that would balance these aspirations through all-encompassing programs of social insurance. We would retain a private economy, but it would be carefully managed in order to curb its ill effects, and a large portion of its output would be used by the government to address large social problems, lessen inequality, and thus also build greater social solidarity.
Of course, this vision has never been implemented in
full. But it has offered a model, for good and for ill. For the left, it
provided long-term goals, criteria for distinguishing progress from retreat in
making short-term compromises, and a kind of definition of the just society.
For the right, it was a foil to be combated and averted — an archetype of
soulless, stifling bureaucratic hubris — and it helped put objections to
seemingly modest individual leftward steps into a broader, more coherent
context. But both ends of our politics seemed implicitly to agree that, left to
its own momentum, this is where our country was headed — where history would
take us if no one stood athwart it yelling stop.
It is no longer really possible to think so. All over
the developed world, nations are coming to terms with the fact that the
social-democratic welfare state is turning out to be untenable. The reason is
partly institutional: The administrative state is dismally inefficient and
unresponsive, and therefore ill-suited to our age of endless choice and
variety. The reason is also partly cultural and moral: The attempt to rescue
the citizen from the burdens of responsibility has undermined the family,
self-reliance, and self-government. But, in practice, it is above all fiscal:
The welfare state has turned out to be unaffordable, dependent as it is upon
dubious economics and the demographic model of a bygone era. Sustaining
existing programs of social insurance, let alone continuing to build new ones
on the social-democratic model, has become increasingly difficult in recent
years, and projections for the coming decades paint an impossibly grim and
baleful picture. There is simply no way that Europe, Japan, or America can
actually go where the economists' long-term charts now point — to debts that
utterly overwhelm their productive capacities, governments that do almost
nothing but support the elderly, and economies with no room for dynamism, for
growth, or for youth. Some change must come, and so it will.
But fully grasping this reality will not be easy. Our
attachment to the social-democratic vision means that we tend to equate its
exhaustion with our own exhaustion, and so to fall into a most un-American
melancholy. On the left, fear of decline is now answered only with false hope
that the dream may yet be saved through clever tinkering at the edges. On the
right, the coming collapse of the liberal welfare state brings calls for
austerity — for less of the same — which only highlight the degree to which
conservatives, too, are stuck in the social-democratic mindset.
The fact is that we do not face a choice between the
liberal welfare state on one hand and austerity on the other. Those are two
sides of the same coin: Austerity and decline are what will come if we do not
reform the welfare state. The choice we face is between that combination and a
different approach to balancing our society's deepest aspirations. America
still has a little time to find such an alternative. Our moment of reckoning is
coming, but it is not yet here. We have perhaps a decade in which to avert it
and to foster again the preconditions for growth and opportunity without
forcing a great disruption in the lives of millions, if we start now.
But we do not yet know quite how. The answer will not
come from the left, which is far too committed to the old vision to accept its
fate and contemplate alternatives. It must therefore emerge from the right.
Conservatives must produce not only arguments against the liberal welfare state
but also a different vision, a different answer to the question of how we might
balance our aspirations. It must be a vision that emphasizes the pursuit of
economic growth, republican virtues, and social mobility over economic
security, value-neutral welfare, and material equality; that redefines the
safety net as a means of making the poor more independent rather than making
the middle class less so; and that translates these ideals into institutional
forms that suit our modern, dynamic society.
That different vision is now beginning to take shape.
Slowly, bit by bit, we are starting to see what must replace our welfare state.
A CENTURY OF TRYING
When an intelligent and charismatic liberal president
was elected in the midst of the most serious economic crisis in a generation in
2008, many on the left believed they were witnessing at last the triumph of the
social-democratic dream in America. The Great Recession, they thought, could
finally push aside the traditional American resistance to that dream, and
create a desire for security that would yield the perfect atmosphere for the
advancement of their cause. An enormous expansion of the government's role in
the health sector enacted a year after Obama's inauguration lent further
credence to this view.
But what seemed like the long-awaited triumph of the
liberal agenda in America may actually prove to be its unraveling. When
historians consider it in retrospect, the economic crisis of 2008 might well be
seen as having marked the beginning of the end of the social-democratic welfare
state. It will have done so by making suddenly urgent what was otherwise a
gradually oncoming problem. By simultaneously showing us what a terrible debt
crisis might feel like, sparking a federal spending spree that much of the
public very quickly deemed excessive, and making more immediate the otherwise
slowly approaching collapse of our entitlement system, the events of the past
few years forced many Americans to wonder whether we were not headed toward an
abyss.
This conflation of short- and medium-term problems —
of annual deficits with retirement liabilities, of sluggish growth with the
burden of debt, of the Obama agenda with the broader social-democratic project
— is in one sense an error, of course. But it is not ultimately an error.
Indeed, it is a powerfully clarifying synthesis, which has given us a vision of
our future: The fiscal crisis we face is an extended and expanded
version of our deficit problem; the recession from which we are emerging was a
preview of life under suffocating debt; the Obama agenda does seek
incrementally to advance the larger social-democratic vision — especially on
the health-care front, where that vision has seen its greatest fiscal failures.
In each case, we have become more powerfully aware of the grave troubles that
await us if we do not reform our welfare state — as though the frog in the pot
got a glimpse of just how hot the water was about to get. This has made a
growing number of Americans (though surely still not a majority) open to
changing our ways while there remains a little time to do so, and has raised
the possibility of gradually putting not only one program or another but the broad
vision at the heart of our politics on the table.
That vision begins with the belief that capitalism,
while capable of producing great prosperity, leaves a great many people
profoundly insecure, and so must be both strictly controlled by a system of robust
regulations and balanced off by a system of robust social insurance. From birth
to death, citizens should be ensconced in a series of protections and benefits
intended to shield them from the harsh edges of the market and allow them to
pursue dignified, fulfilling lives: universal child care, universal health
care, universal public schooling and higher education, welfare benefits for the
poor, generous labor protections for workers, dexterous management of the
levers of the economy to ease the cycles of boom and bust, skillful direction
of public funds to spur private productivity and efficiency, and, finally,
pensions for the elderly. Each component would be overseen by a competent and
rational bureaucracy, and the whole would make for a system that is not only
beneficent but unifying and dignifying, and that enables the pursuit of common
national goals and ideals.
This system would encompass all citizens, not only the
poor, in an effort to overcome some of the social consequences of the
iniquities inherent in a capitalist economy. As Robert Kuttner, founding editor
of the liberal American Prospect magazine, has put it:
"In a democratic polity that also happens to be a highly unequal market
economy, there is immense civic value to treating middle-class and poor people
alike. A common social security program, or medical care program, or public
school program, helps to create the kind of cohesion that Europe's social
democrats like to call ‘social solidarity' — a sense that basic humanity and
citizenship in the political community require equal treatment in at least some
areas of economic life."
Thus, the inequality, dislocation, and isolation
caused by capitalism could be remedied together, and in a way that would also
help to get the middle class invested in the system (not to say dependent on
it) and help society to grow increasingly rational and enlightened under the
guidance of an educated and benevolent governing class. This kind of welfare
state aims not just at keeping the poor above a certain minimum level of
subsistence and helping them rise, but at a new arrangement of society to be
achieved by the redistribution of resources and responsibilities.
Of course these are the general outlines of a vision
of society, not particular planks of a policy agenda. But that vision has acted
in the background of American (and European) politics for a century, shaping
policy proposals and political battles large and small.
In our country it has often had to be pursued almost
in stealth, by incremental steps undertaken as events permit. The Democratic
Party has never made a full-throated case for the broader vision in the way
that some European social democrats have. Part of the reason is surely
America's basic orientation toward government. Ours may be the only government
to arise out of a distrust of government. Again and again in our history,
passionate waves of resistance to authority have rattled our politics, while
periods of trust in the state have been rare. The left has sought to use those
rare moments — particularly the emergency of the Great Depression and the
unique stretch of relative peace and prosperity of the early 1960s — to advance
the welfare state where it could. Even then, however, it always faced staunch
resistance, and proceeded by fits and starts — enacting one program or another
in the hope of coming back for more when circumstances allowed it.
This has left us with a somewhat disjointed
arrangement of welfare-state programs, tilted disproportionately toward the
elderly — who are the foremost beneficiaries of our two largest entitlement
programs (Social Security and Medicare) and receive more than a quarter of the
benefits provided by the third largest (Medicaid). The other elements of our
welfare state have taken the form of the many dozens of smaller, more targeted
programs — from Head Start to public housing to the Children's Health Insurance
Program — that fill out the federal government's massive entitlement and
domestic discretionary budgets. All of these individual programs, large and small,
fit into a broader pattern and trajectory defined by the social-democratic
ideal. And because that ideal has largely functioned in the background, it has
been possible to present and understand these incremental steps as mere
pragmatism, while opposition to them has had to present itself as radical and
ideological.
Throughout much of the 20th century,
there was a sense on the left (and therefore among most of our cultural and
intellectual elite) that steps along the social-democratic trajectory constituted
progress — that this was where we were fated to go, however long it might take.
This sense was powerfully palpable in the debate surrounding the latest major
step along that path, which was taken just last year through the health-care
reforms of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act. Throughout that
debate, the word "historic" was constantly on the lips of the bill's
champions, and the notion that the bill was the latest in a long line of
consistent forward steps was everywhere in the air. President Obama, when
signing the measure, described it as the culmination of "almost a century
of trying," and said the law contained "reforms that generations of
Americans have fought for and marched for and hungered to see." As House Speaker
Nancy Pelosi called the final vote to a close, she used the same gavel that had
been used when the House voted to enact the Medicare and Medicaid programs in
1965, to emphasize the point that these were all elements of one large project.
THE PASSING OF AN ILLUSION
But Pelosi's chosen symbol stood for more than she
intended. While the enactment of the two massive health-care entitlements of
the Great Society period may have represented the peak of social-democratic
activism in America, those two entitlements now also represent the failure of
the social-democratic vision in practice. They have grown so unwieldy and
expensive as to be thoroughly unsustainable, and in the process have helped
inflate costs in the broader health-care sector in ways that now imperil the
nation's fiscal future. The new health-care entitlement enacted last year
promises to do more of the same, and thus to place even further stress on the
crumbling foundations of our welfare state.
Nearly all of the dozens of small and large programs
that compose our welfare state have come to exhibit similar problems:
out-of-control costs, mediocre results, harmful unintended consequences, and by
now a growing sense of inadequacy and exhaustion. This combination of problems
is hardly a coincidence; it runs to the heart of the social-democratic project.
The three key arguments in favor of this vision of the welfare state — its
rationality and efficiency, its morality and capacity for unifying society, and
its economic benefits — all turn out in reality to be among its foremost
failings.
First, the welfare state functions in practice through
the administrative state — the network of public agencies that employ technical
expertise and bureaucratic management to enforce rules and provide benefits and
services. The case for such bureaucracy is a case for impartial efficiency — an
argument that a rationally organized institution following strict rules and
exercising power for the public good should be the most fair, economical, and
convenient way to administer large programs. This approach, grounded in the
Progressive faith in scientific administration, appeals to the technocratic
inclinations of the modern left, but it turns out to be poorly suited to
governing actual people — especially in our dynamic modern economy.
Human societies do not work by obeying orderly
commands from central managers, however well meaning; they work through the
erratic interplay of individual and, even more, of familial and communal
decisions answering locally felt desires and needs. Designed to offer
professional expert management, our bureaucratic institutions assume a society
defined by its material needs and living more or less in stasis, and so they
are often at a loss to contend with a people in constant motion and possessed
of a seemingly infinite imagination for cultural and commercial innovation. The
result is gross inefficiency — precisely the opposite of what the
administrative state is intended to yield.
In our everyday experience, the bureaucratic state
presents itself not as a benevolent provider and protector but as a corpulent
behemoth — flabby, slow, and expressionless, unmoved by our concerns, demanding
compliance with arcane and seemingly meaningless rules as it breathes musty air
in our faces and sends us to the back of the line. Largely free of competition,
most administrative agencies do not have to answer directly to public
preferences, and so have developed in ways that make their own operations
easier (or their own employees more contented) but that grow increasingly
distant from the way we live.
Unresponsive ineptitude is not merely an annoyance.
The sluggishness of the welfare state drains it of its moral force. The
crushing weight of bureaucracy permits neither efficiency nor idealism. It thus
robs us of a good part of the energy of democratic capitalism and encourages a
corrosive cynicism that cannot help but undermine the moral aims of the
social-democratic vision.
Worse yet, because the institutions of the welfare
state are intended to be partial substitutes for traditional familial, social,
religious, and cultural mediating institutions, their growth weakens the very
structures that might balance our society's restless quest for prosperity and
novelty and might replenish our supply of idealism.
This is the second major failing of this vision of
society — a kind of spiritual failing. Under the rules of the modern welfare
state, we give up a portion of the capacity to provide for ourselves and in
return are freed from a portion of the obligation to discipline ourselves.
Increasing economic collectivism enables increasing moral individualism, both
of which leave us with less responsibility, and therefore with less grounded
and meaningful lives.
Moreover, because all citizens — not only the poor —
become recipients of benefits, people in the middle class come to approach
their government as claimants, not as self-governing citizens, and to approach
the social safety net not as a great majority of givers eager to make sure that
a small minority of recipients are spared from devastating poverty but as a
mass of dependents demanding what they are owed. It is hard to imagine an ethic
better suited to undermining the moral basis of a free society.
Meanwhile, because public programs can never truly
take the place of traditional mediating institutions, the people who most
depend upon the welfare state are relegated to a moral vacuum. Rather than
strengthening social bonds, the rise of the welfare state has precipitated the
collapse of family and community, especially among the poor.
This was not the purpose of our welfare state, but it
is among its many unintended consequences. As Irving Kristol put it in 1997,
"The secular, social-democratic founders of the modern welfare state
really did think that in the kind of welfare state we have today people would
be more public-spirited, more high-minded, more humanly ‘fulfilled.'" They
were wrong about this for the same reason that their expectations of the
administrative state have proven misguided — because their understanding of the
human person was far too shallow and emaciated. They assumed that moral
problems were functions of material problems, so that addressing the latter
would resolve the former, when the opposite is more often the case. And guided
by the ethic of the modern left, they imagined that traditional institutions
like the family, the church, and the local association were sources of
division, prejudice, and backwardness, rather than essential pillars of our
moral lives. The failure of the social-democratic vision is, in this sense,
fundamentally a failure of moral wisdom.
That is not to say, of course, that it did not produce
positive benefits along the way. Indeed, the era in which the social-democratic
vision has dominated our politics has hardly been an age of decline for America
— it has been, if anything, the American century. And it has been a time of
diminishing poverty and rising standards of living. But it is now becoming
apparent that this was achieved by our spending our capital (economic, moral,
and human) without replenishing it, and that this failure, too, is a defining
characteristic of the social-democratic vision.
America's unchallenged economic prowess in the wake of
the Second World War, and the resulting surge of growth and prosperity, were
essential to enabling the flurry of social-democratic activism we know as the
Great Society, and which continues to define the basic shape of our domestic
policy. Flush with revenue and stirred by the promise of technocratic mastery,
our government took on immense entitlement commitments and major social reforms
in that era, and these have certainly had some of their intended consequences.
But they have also struck at the roots (economic and especially moral) of our
ability to sustain our strength. The collapse of the family among the poor —
powerfully propelled by the ethic of social democracy and by a horrendously
designed welfare system that was not improved until the mid-1990s — has vastly
worsened social and economic inequality in America, and the capacity of
generations to rise out of poverty. Our entitlement commitments, particularly
those of the massive health-care entitlements enacted in the 1960s, stand to
make ever-greater demands on our economic strength, and so to sap our potential
to sustain that strength. And our system of age-based wealth transfers relies
upon a demographic model that the welfare state seriously undermines, and that
now bears no relation to the reality of American life. In the age of social
democracy, we have failed to think generationally, and so have failed to think of
the prerequisites for renewal.
These trends all come together in the third major
failing of our welfare state, and the one that, more than any other, may yet
bring about real change: its economic breakdown. Simply put, we cannot afford
to preserve our welfare state in anything like its present form.
The heart of the problem is the heart of our welfare
state: our entitlement system. Age-based wealth transfers in an aging society
are obviously problematic. As Americans are living longer and having fewer children
(and as the Baby Boomers retire at a rate of 10,000 people per day over the
next 20 years), the ratio of workers paying taxes to retirees collecting
benefits is falling precipitously — from 16 workers per retiree in 1950 to just
three today, and closer to two in the coming decades. This means that even the
simplest and least troubled of our age-based transfer programs — the Social
Security program — is facing serious problems: Social Security ran a deficit
for the first time last year, and the Congressional Budget Office estimates it
will continue to do so from now on unless its structure is reformed. Add to
that our exploding health-care costs — which the design of our health-care
entitlements severely exacerbates — and you will begin to get a sense of the
problem we confront. The trustees of Social Security and Medicare now estimate
that the two programs together have an unfunded long-term liability of $46
trillion — about $30 trillion of it in Medicare. Meanwhile, Medicaid, which
provides health coverage to the poor, is now nearly as expensive as Medicare —
costing more than half a trillion dollars a year, and growing swiftly.
The growth of these programs threatens to swallow the
federal budget. The CBO estimates that, by 2025, Medicare, Medicaid, Social
Security, and interest payments on the debt alone will consume every last cent
of federal revenues, leaving all discretionary spending to be funded by
borrowing. And that spending, too, has been growing by leaps and bounds
recently — domestic discretionary spending has increased by 25% in just the
past three years.
That explosion in discretionary spending is why our
immediate budget picture is so bleak, but the fact that an entitlement crisis
waits just around the corner means that there is no clear boundary any longer
between our short-term and our longer-term fiscal problems. Our debt has begun
to balloon, and absent major reforms, it will not stop. CBO figures show that,
if current policies remain in place, the national debt will grow much faster than
the economy in the coming years: A decade from now, the United States will owe
nearly $20 trillion — more than three times what we owed in 2008. At that
point, interest payments alone will consume about $800 billion a year — more
than four times as much as they did in 2008. And the entitlement crisis will
only just be getting underway.
This explosion of both discretionary and entitlement
spending is like nothing our country has ever experienced, and it is why our
welfare state is unsustainable. The graph below traces the national debt from
1790 through 2050, using historical figures (the solid line) and projections
(marked by dashes) from the Congressional Budget Office. Previous spikes in the
debt can be traced to discrete events in our history — the Civil War, the two
world wars, and the Great Depression. But the spike that is now beginning,
which will be worse by far than any we have seen before, is a function of the
fiscal collapse of our welfare state.
If we do not change course, by 2030, America's
national debt will be nearly twice the size of the economy; by 2050, it will be
roughly three times the size of the economy and will continue to grow from
there. Such massive and unprecedented debt will make it impossible for America
to experience anything like the growth and prosperity that marked the post-war
era. Simply paying interest on this debt, let alone funding the activities of
government, will require more and more borrowing, as well as cuts in other areas
and major tax increases. It will also leave us exposed to tremendous risk of
inflation and dependent on the goodwill of our lenders. It will leave future
generations saddled with an immense burden but unable to enjoy the benefits of
much of what they will be paying for, since it will make it impossible to
sustain our welfare state in anything like its current form.
Japan and the nations of Western Europe are looking at
similar projections. And in our country, many state governments are facing
their own dire fiscal prospects as a result of similarly unsustainable
retirement commitments and spending patterns. This is where the
social-democratic project has gotten us. If we simply follow this trajectory,
then future generations considering this chart will have no doubt as to just
when the turning point came, and just which generation failed to keep its
charge.
It is unimaginable that the world's foremost economic
power would do this to itself by choice. And we will not. We will change
course.
DEMOCRATIC CAPITALISM
Changing course will not be easy, to be sure. It will
require extraordinary sacrifices from today's young Americans, who will need to
continue paying the taxes necessary to support the retirements of their parents
and grandparents while denying themselves the same level of benefits so their
children and grandchildren can thrive. To persuade them to make such
sacrifices, our political leaders will need to offer them a plausible program
of reform, and an appealing vision of American life beyond the dream of social
democracy.
That vision cannot be a purist fantasy. It must be a
serious answer — an answer better suited to a proper understanding of human
nature and American life — to the same question that motivated the
social-democratic ideal: How do we balance our aspirations to prosperity and
virtue and build a thriving society that makes its wealth and promise
accessible to all?
In their struggle with the left these past 60 years,
conservatives have too often responded to the social-democratic vision by
arguing with it in the abstract. Constitutionalism, natural rights,
libertarianism, traditionalism — all offered powerful objections to the welfare
state, but few viable alternatives. Conservatives have thus lacked specificity
on policy, and so have been left struggling to explain themselves to the
public. There have, of course, been exceptions (most notably the economic
reforms of the 1980s and the welfare reforms of the 1990s). On the whole,
however, conservatives have focused on the size and scope of government, but
not on its proper purposes — on yelling stop, but not on where to go instead.
Now, as the social-democratic dream grows truly
bankrupt and untenable, America finds itself governed by a reactionary party
and a conservative party. The reactionary party, the Democratic Party, its head
in the sand and its mind adrift in false nostalgia, insists that nothing is
wrong, and that the welfare state requires little more than tinkering at the
edges, and indeed further expansions. It lives always with the model of the
Great Society in mind, and fails to grasp the ruin it threatens to bring upon
the rising generation. It cannot imagine a different approach.
The conservative party, the Republican Party, still
struggles for a vocabulary of resistance, and so has not taken up in earnest
the vocabulary of alternatives. It calls on the spirit of the founders, but not
on their genius for designing institutions; it shadowboxes Progressives who no
longer exist (and whose successors, running on fumes and inertia, have nowhere
near the intellectual depth to take up their case); it insists that our problem
is just too much government.
But if the Republican Party is to be a truly
conservative party, it will need to think its way to an agenda of conservative
reform. Conservatism is reformist at its core, combining, as Edmund Burke put
it, "a disposition to preserve and an ability to improve," and so
responding to the changing world by means that seek to strengthen what is most
essential. A conservative vision would be driven not by a desire to "fundamentally
transform America" (as Barack Obama promised to do in 2008), but rather by
an idea of what we want to be that is the best form of what we are. It would
look to make our institutions suit us better, and so to make them serve us
better and more effectively help us improve ourselves.
Our welfare state is very poorly suited to the kind of
society we are — an aging society in which older people are, on the whole,
wealthier than younger people. And it is very poorly suited to the kind of
society we want to be — enterprising and vibrant, with a free economy, devoted
to social mobility and eager to offer a hand up to the poor. A successful
reform agenda would have to take account of both.
It would begin not from the assumption that capitalism
is dehumanizing, but rather from the sense that too many people do not have
access to capitalism's benefits. It would start not from the presumption that
traditional practices and institutions must be overcome by rational
administration, but rather from the firm conviction that family, church, and
civil society are the means by which human beings find fulfillment and are
essential counterweights to the market. It would reject the notion that
universal dependence can build solidarity, and insist instead that only self-reliance,
responsibility, and discipline can build mutual respect and character in a free
society. It would seek to help the poor not with an empty promise of material
equality but with a fervent commitment to upward mobility. It would reject the
top-down bureaucratic state in favor of consumer choice and competition. It
would insist on the distinction between a welfare program and a welfare state —
between directed efforts to help the poor avail themselves of meaningful
opportunities and a broad project to remake society along social-democratic
lines.
The appeal of such a re-orientation is not that it is
radical but that it is moderate — that it suits us. And for now, there is even
still time to pursue it by moderate means — to allow today's retirees and near-retirees
to receive all the benefits they have been promised as we transform our
institutions going forward.
It would be folly, of course, to propose a detailed
policy platform that would meet these criteria. Just as the left for a century
had not a precise agenda but a general vision of what its ideal outcome would
look like — a vision that could guide incremental steps and provide criteria
for judging compromises — so the conservative vision, the ideal of democratic
capitalism, can exist only in outline. But over the past half-decade, in the
work of conservative scholars, intellectuals, and politicians, just such an
outline has been emerging.
It would begin with a simple and predictable tax
system, with a broad base and low rates, free of most of today's deductions and
exclusions. The only three worth keeping in the individual tax code are the tax
exemption for retirement savings (which are far preferable to universal cash
benefits to retirees), a unified child tax credit (to encourage parenthood and to
offset the mistreatment of parents in the tax code), and the charitable-giving
deduction (since a reduction in government's role in social welfare must be met
with an increase in the role of civil society, which should be encouraged).
These three exemptions are directed precisely to the needs of a modern society,
and to addressing the three broad failings of the social-democratic welfare
state. The corporate tax code should similarly be dramatically broadened and
flattened to encourage growth, which must be the foremost goal of economic
policy.
Second, essentially all government benefits —
including benefits for the elderly — should be means-tested so that those in
greater need receive more help and those who are not needy do not become
dependent on public support. Most retirees would still receive some public
benefits (and the poorest could well get more than they do now), but the design
of our welfare programs would avoid creating the misimpression that they are
savings programs. People who are already retired or nearly so today should be
exempted from such means-testing, as they have planned for decades around the
existing system; Americans below 55 or so, however, should expect public help
only if they are in need once they retire. Means-testing should, to the extent
possible, be designed to avoid discouraging saving and work. And private
retirement savings should be strongly encouraged and incentivized, so that
people who have the means would build private nest eggs with less reliance on
government.
Third, we should advance a consumer-based health-care
system — backed with fixed, means-tested premium supports — in which
individuals purchase their own insurance in a free market regulated largely by
the states. Such a system would, over time, replace today's tax exclusion for
employer-based coverage (which would be converted into a flat universal tax
credit for the purchase of insurance) as well as Medicare and Medicaid (which
would become add-ons to that credit based on wealth, age, and health — again
leaving today's retirees or near-retirees with today's benefits). This would
create a single continuous system in which the poor and the old would still
have heavily subsidized coverage and much of the middle class would still have
moderately subsidized coverage, but everyone would make real purchasing
decisions and keep the same insurance as his circumstances changed. This
approach would seek to let people be active consumers, rather than passive
recipients of benefits — which would be good both for the federal budget (since
consumer pressure in a free market keeps costs down far better than price
controls) and for the character of our nation.
Fourth, we should gradually but significantly reduce
domestic discretionary spending, ending most of the discretionary Great Society
programs and folding others into block grants to the states. The federal
government's role in the provision of social services should be minimal, and
largely limited to helping the states and the institutions of civil society
better carry out their missions. It would still have some role as an investor
(in infrastructure and education, above all), but this too should be strictly
targeted to essential public needs that the private sector would not meet, and
block-granted to the states whenever possible. Government at all levels should
also look to contract its remaining functions out to the private sector where
it can, both to improve efficiency and to avoid harmful conflicts between the
government's obligations to the people it serves and its obligations to the
people it employs — conflicts that have been rampant in our time.
Fifth, we should reduce the reach of the
administrative state, paring back all but essential regulations and protections
and adopting over time an ethic of keeping the playing field level rather than
micromanaging market forces, and of preferring set rules (in regulation, in
monetary policy, and elsewhere) to administrative discretion.
Obviously, these are only general principles and aims.
And at least as important as what they contain is what they do not — what is
left to the sphere of the family, religion, and civil society. Government must
see itself as an ally and supporter of these crucial mediating institutions,
not as a substitute for them. Its role is to sustain the preconditions for
social, cultural, and economic vitality.
But these general aims offer a stark contrast to the
general aims of the social-democratic vision of society — a very different
understanding of what it is about capitalism that needs to be tempered and
balanced, of what the sources of social solidarity really are, of the
significance of responsibility and choice, and of the deepest meaning of the
American experiment. They outline a government that is smaller but more
effective, and gesture toward a vision of American public life that is
economically sustainable and morally rich and responsible.
MODEST MEANS AND MODEST ENDS
Champions of our welfare state view democratic
capitalism as the grim reality to be overcome and social democracy as the
elevated ideal to be realized. But this has it backwards. The vision of social
democracy has dominated our political life for many decades, but it is failing
us. Real democratic capitalism — a free society with a free economy and a
commitment to help every citizen enjoy the benefits of both — is the ideal that
must guide the work of American domestic policy in the coming years.
That ideal, like any ideal, will never be perfectly
realized. The planks roughly sketched above are not dogmas but general guides
for compromise and barter. They can help us discern steps forward from steps
backward, and give us a direction to aim for. Every step in this direction,
however small and unsatisfying, should be welcomed, and every step will help to
ease our way to the next. Some steps (especially those involving health care
and entitlements) are more urgent than others, but all point in the same
direction and all can be advanced incrementally.
Even under the best of circumstances, if these policy
pillars were to be fully enacted, we would still have a very sizable
government, and no shortage of bureaucracy and inefficiency. There would still
be plenty for Atlas to shrug about. But some of the gravest threats to our
future would be addressed, and the basic orientation of our politics would be
made friendlier to our deepest aspirations. Politics, after all, is not about a
destination but about sustaining the conditions that allow citizens to live
thriving private lives and a thriving national life. That is always a matter of
adjustments and modifications in search of an arrangement of policies and
institutions well suited to our character, our needs, our strengths and
weaknesses, and our priorities.
Conservatives should therefore not expect to ever
simply win the argument. Our challenge, rather, is to dominate the argument —
to offer the vision that implicitly sets the tone for our common life. The key
to doing so is the emergence of a policy-oriented conservatism, one able to
make gainful compromises not because it is ambivalent about its own aims or
tentative in its commitment to them but because it knows exactly what it wants
— a thriving free society with a market economy, strong families, a devotion to
country, and a commitment to the value of every life — and knows that this can
(indeed must) be obtained gradually, by a mix of persuasion and proof. Such an
approach must always remain grounded in the principles of American life — the
principles of the Declaration of Independence and the Constitution, of the
Western tradition and of classical liberalism. But it must also translate those
principles into policy particulars. In our politics, battles over ideas are won
in practice, not in theory.
Recent decades have offered some examples of such an
approach — from welfare reform to the urban policing revolution — but they have
been too few and far between. There are good reasons to hope that just such an
approach is now emerging more broadly on the right, and good reasons to
encourage and foster its emergence.
It could hardly come too soon. We need it not only
because we are increasingly drowning in debt, and not only because our
governing institutions are growing exhausted and out of touch with reality. We
need it above all because the decline of the social-democratic welfare state
risks persuading us, falsely, that America's fate is to decline along with it.
On the contrary, America's fate is, as it always has been, to show the world by
example how a commitment to human liberty and equality, an application of
republican virtues, a belief in individual ingenuity and drive, and an
unswerving devotion to helping the least among us rise can defy the cynics and
the pessimists, and can make future generations proud to succeed us.
No comments:
Post a Comment