Complaints from savers about low rates of return on
their money have reached the business page of the New
York Times. According to the Times, when
Bill Taren, a retiree living near Orlando, Florida, learned that his credit
union would pay just 0.4 percent interest on his savings, he decided to take
the money out of the bank and put it into his mattress because, he said, “at
least there we can see the cash.”
It was worse for Julie Moscove of
Fort Lauderdale, Florida. Over the last four years, she has watched her
interest income drop from $2,000 a month to $400 a month. She said, “It’s
ridiculous. I cut coupons now.”
And Dorothy Brooks has been forced to go back to work in order to
supplement what’s left of her retirement income, after being retired for the
last 10 years:
I got hit a couple of years ago pretty badly in the
stock market, so now my savings are weighted mostly toward bonds. Now both
investments are terrible. And I can’t put my money in a money-market account
because that’s crazy. That just pays nothing.
Keynesian economic policies allegedly designed (and
sold to the American people) to stimulate the economy are actually having the
perverse effect of stimulating government spending and putting off the
inevitable day of reckoning when interest rates inevitably begin to rise.
As the Times writer Catherine Rampell noted:
Though bad for people trying to live off their savings, low interest rates happen to be quite good for anyone borrowing money, like governments themselves.
Over time, interest rates below the inflation rate
allow governments to refinance, erode or liquidate their debt, making it easier
to live within their budgets without having to resort to more unpalatable
spending cuts or tax increases.
In the nearly four years that the Fed set its
benchmark interest rate at zero, the government has saved trillions of dollars
in interest payments. If interest rates today were what they were in 2007, the
Treasury would be paying about twice as much to service its debt.
Those numbers are mind-numbingly huge. The federal
government currently owes $16 trillion and is paying more than $350 billion a
year in interest to its lenders. If interest rates rise just
to the level where they were in 2007, prior to the beginning of the Great
Recession, those payments would double to more than $700 billion. That’s close
to a third of the entire revenue stream of the government.
The Keynesian "magic" isn’t working in the
housing market either. Despite the lowest financing rates in history, people
are not flocking to buy new homes. Part of the reason is that many have damaged
credit, thanks to the recession, and can’t qualify. Part is because there is
such a huge overhang of bank-owned real estate still waiting to be cleared from
the market. Part is the unknown number of homes waiting to come onto the market
when prices do eventually start to rise so that homeowners can get out from
under onerous mortgage payments. Most important is the downsizing taking place
as the Baby Boomers retire and put their now-too-large homes on the market and
move to smaller quarters in town houses and condominium developments.
Besides, why would investors “rush in” to take
advantage of low rates when they know that the Fed is determined to keep them
low for years to come?
Pension funds are also being adversely affected.
Pension plans rely on only two sources to provide the funds for their
beneficiaries: contributions from workers and their employers, and earnings on
invested assets. As those earnings decline, contributions must increase, or the
beneficiaries will be shorted when they retire. Many pension plans have assumed
they could earn seven to eight percent on their assets, but the real world of
unintended consequences is forcing them to reduce those estimates. This
increases the level of contributions the plans’ sponsors and participants must
make to keep the plans solvent. This is creating shortfalls and severe
underfunding. The inevitable result for plans’ beneficiaries is easy to see:
lower payouts, starting later.
The insurance industry is also being hit by the low
interest rates imposed by the Fed. When they can’t earn enough to pay out the
promised benefits, premiums for such instruments as annuities and
long-term-care policies must go up. Most policies already in force cannot have
their premiums raised, and so premiums for new policyholders go up instead. This makes those policies less attractive.
Something else is going on that few are paying
attention to: the bond market “bubble.” Ever since interest rates hit 21
percent in the early 1980s, long term bonds have been in a bull market (bond
values move inversely to interest rates). And the holders of long-term
bonds — pension plans, well-to-do individuals, and investors — have
reaped enormous profits as their holdings have increased in value. But that
game is over.
The only way for interest rates to go is up. When that
happens, bond values will begin to fall. If they fall sufficiently, bond
holders will begin to sell before they get hurt, putting more pressure on the
market, reducing prices further.
This is the classic definition of a “bubble,” and just
one more unintended consequence of keeping interest rates low, all in obedience
to the Keynesian dictum that eventually — somehow — the economy will
start to revive.
One knows that the game is nearly over when high-level
officials of the Federal Reserve itself begin to issue warnings. James Bullard,
CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, gave a speech recently, telling the Union
League Club of Chicago:
In principle, the low real interest rates should encourage younger generations to borrow against their future income prospects and consume more today. However, this demographic group faces high unemployment rates and tighter borrowing constraints, which may limit its ability and willingness to leverage up to finance consumption.
Consequently, the consumption of the older generations may be damaged by the low real interest rates without any countervailing increase in consumption by other households in the economy.
In this sense, the policy could be counterproductive.
“Counterproductive” is how a supporter of failed
Keynesian stimulus and zero interest rates says, “We may have made a serious
mistake.”
Indeed they have. Here’s the rule: If capital is
punished, there will be less of it. At present capital is being extracted from
those who have it and given to the federal government who needs it to pay its
bills. It avoids, for the time being at least, the necessity of going directly
to taxpayers.
That’s the ultimate unintended consequence.
No comments:
Post a Comment