By Stephen Davies
Earlier this year the world lost one of its most
original and insightful scholars with the death of Elinor Ostrom. Unlike some
winners of the Nobel Prize for economics, Ostrom will be inspiring research and
fresh thinking for many years to come. One of her central insights was that
human beings have a huge capacity to create institutions that conserve scarce
resources and prevent predatory behavior without relying on political power or
market exchanges. This means we should move away from the simple dichotomies
public versus private, State versus market, and government regulation versus
market exchange.
In particular we should stop
thinking we must choose between regulation (control by government) on the one
hand and unregulated private action on the other. The reality is more complex.
Rules and regulations govern many activities but can have all kinds of sources
other than the State.
Nor do things end there.
Another of Ostrom’s insights is that complex human institutions and social
systems frequently are governed not by explicit rules or laws but rather by
generally understood norms and expectations, with accepted penalties for
violation. Again, these are created not by diktat or legislation but
spontaneously, by human interaction, yet they bind and regulate the actions of
individuals as tightly as any printed code or regulation—often more so.
A classic, and highly topical,
example is provided by the history of financial markets and exchanges,
particularly the London Stock Exchange. Not understanding either the history or
Ostrom’s insight can lead to a damaging misunderstanding of both the recent
past and the present. Such misunderstanding is found on both sides of the
conventional argument.
The widely held view of the
history of the exchange goes something like this: Up to 1986 the financial
market in London was highly regulated, but then the Thatcher government freed
it of regulation. For some this was the start of a golden era for the City of
London, with rapid growth, the breaking of an “old boy network,” and a whole
series of efficiency gains, while for others it was the beginning of disastrous
unregulated dog-eat-dog competition. Both accounts misunderstand both the
situation before the “Big Bang” of 1986 and the nature of what came afterward.
Looking at London as one of Ostrom’s communities gives us a clearer picture.
The stock exchange, and the
wider financial markets of the city, were indeed highly regulated before 1986.
However, the regulations in question did not come from the British government.
Rather they were created, articulated, and enforced in the classic way that
Ostrom’s work recognized—by private action within a social group. The exchange
was formed in 1773 as a private club and remained one up to 1986. The first
modern stock exchange appeared in Antwerp in the Netherlands in the sixteenth
century. In imitation the English Crown set up a Royal Exchange in London in
1571. During the later seventeenth century, trading in stocks and shares became
an increasingly important activity and there were repeated attempts by the
government to regulate it by statute. This drove much of the activity away from
official exchanges and into the coffeehouses and streets, notably Exchange
Alley near the new Bank of England. In 1773 about 150 stockbrokers formed a
club that became the London Stock Exchange (as it remained until it became a
public limited company in 1986). This involved the drawing up of formal rules
to govern membership and trading, which were written down in 1812.
The rules governing the buying
and selling of securities were extensive and explicit but were produced by the
voluntary association of the members. It never had a statutory monopoly of such
trade, so any group of investors or brokers could set up a rival. However,
although regional exchanges existed in centers such as Manchester, Liverpool,
and Glasgow, no challenger emerged. It also faced competition from exchanges
elsewhere in Europe and North America, such as New York, Frankfurt, and Paris.
The rules enforced by the London exchange stipulated among other things that
commissions were fixed and that brokers could not trade on their own accounts. (They were price takers, not price makers.)
However, this was not the full
story. The process that had produced the association and rules of the exchange
also generated complex norms and expectations that governed the behavior of
participants in the London market without being explicitly articulated. These
were summarized in the saying that became the official motto of the exchange in
1923: “My word is my bond.” All kinds of major business deals would be
undertaken with only the most minimal paperwork and legal paraphernalia;
sometimes they were built on nothing more than a handshake. To break an
undertaking or to knowingly give false information so as to mislead one’s
counterparty to his disadvantage was simply unthinkable for most. Human nature
being what it is, there were of course people who did not adhere to these
norms, and scandals occurred. There were severe penalties for this, quite
independent of any criminal or civil sanction. Essentially the offender would
never be able to do business in the city again and would become a social
outcast. This was much more effective than people today might imagine.
What happened in 1986 was not
a matter of deregulation as commonly understood. Rather it saw the replacement
of Ostrom-style social regulation by government regulation. An official
government body—the Competition Commission—held that the rules of the exchange,
despite their ultimately voluntary and non-monopolistic nature, restricted
competition and were economically inefficient. The subsequent statutory action
swept away all the controls and regulations that voluntary club action had
produced.
However, it did not stop at
that. A massive body of State regulation was created, which has governed ever
since and has grown in both size and complexity. Most of the norm-based
controls have gradually faded away, replaced by ever-more extensive and
explicit written regulation. The problem of course is that the attempt to
capture and cover every eventuality in this way is not only futile but
counterproductive, since it creates opportunities for the unscrupulous to
benefit by gaming the system, often by flouting the spirit of the rules while
staying within the letter. The informal norm-based way of doing things is
flexible enough to prevent this kind of behavior.
Human beings living in complex
societies need rules and regulations to govern things such as access to resources
and to ensure some do not take advantage of others. One form of governance is
government regulation and legislation. But there are a number of alternatives,
one of which is the private association that generates rules and enforces them
on its members. Provided the club is not “closed” and does not have a State
monopoly (that is, it cannot use force to shut down potential competitors),
this can be much more effective. Moreover, the experience of dealing with other
people in this way generates rules and expectations that are widely shared and
understood even if unarticulated, and these on all the evidence are a more
effective and humane check on predatory behavior than the most elaborate codes
of government regulations.
No comments:
Post a Comment