by Mark Thornton
The senseless Batman killings in Aurora, Colorado, as
well as those that occurred years earlier in Columbine a few miles away, have
something in common with the number one cause of overdose deaths in the United
States and an important potential cause of teen suicide: prescription drugs
approved as safe and effective by the Food and Drug Administration (FDA).
As an Austrian economist, I am not saying that
FDA-approved drugs "caused" these problems. The people who took those
drugs and did those things are the people who "caused" those bad
outcomes. What I am saying is that the FDA is guilty of manipulating
information and people's choices and thereby contributes to all these negative
outcomes.[1] I am also not saying that all FDA-approved drugs
are inherently harmful, ineffective, or should never be used.
Most importantly, FDA-approved drugs and products help
to make Americans fatter, weaker, dumber, sicker, poorer, and in general less
healthy. We have been lulled into substituting prescription drugs for healthy
lifestyles. "You don't need to correct unhealthy conditions in your life,
just take this pill everyday for the rest of your life. The experts at the FDA
have approved it and your doctor has advised you to take them."
Collectively, this process is unconscionable, even though it is now considered
normal.
As the pharmaceutical and medical industries pile up
cash, the health crisis grows and spreads across the country. This is the
irrational world created by the FDA. This powerful government bureaucracy,
coupled with massive government monopolies (e.g., the American Medical
Association, drug patents, certificates of need for hospitals), direct
government subsidies such as Medicare and Medicaid, and indirect subsidies for
comprehensive health insurance, etc., have combined to give America the most
expensive medical industry and the least healthy population in the advanced
world.
The FDA is a government bureaucracy, which Mises showed must be a rule-driven,
rather than market-driven, institution. "Bureaucratic management is
management of affairs which cannot be checked by economic calculation."[2] Hence the affairs governed by bureaucracies grow
increasingly irrational and out of synch with human wants over time. As Mises
demonstrated, the rule-driven bureaucracy is all about violence, not progress:
"The ultimate basis of an all around bureaucratic system is
violence."[3]
For example, we recently saw the FDA fined
GlaxoSmithKline (GSK) $3 billion for illegally marketing their drugs for
unapproved uses. They have fined other drug companies for similar practices.
But do they ever get the job done?
No, the FDA is habitually slow to react, and even when
they do, such fines are just part of the cost of doing business with the FDA.
No people have actually been punished; GSK's stock rose significantly when the
fine was announced, and hardly anyone even noticed the event. How unlike the
free market, where a few tainted pills of Tylenol unleashes weeks of
cable-television news coverage, billions of product recalls, crashing stock
prices, and billions spent correcting the product-safety issue and assuaging
the fears of consumers.[4]
When it comes to drugs, there are the good drugs that are produced and regulated by the
real free marketplace. There are the bad drugs that
are created as a result of government prohibition. Then, with the FDA, things
get ugly. Here there are no social mechanisms to generate
solutions, only a bureaucracy concerned with protecting itself and its power.
The Big Pharma–FDA nexus is just one giant conflict of interest against the
general public.[5] Let us now try to make economic sense of all
this FDA chaos.
Drugs have been used for thousands of years. We now
consume more goods that are considered drugs than ever before. There is no
denying the benefits and economic value of drugs. However, the subject does
raise an often neglected consideration of "harm." Unexpected harm is
the result of underappreciated dangers from the consumption of a good.
In other words, everyone expects to receive more benefits than costs when
buying a good. Our expectations include some known uncertainties (Is this going
to be a good or bad avocado?) and other possible risks (Is this a potentially
dangerous genetically modified avocado?). For our purposes, "harm"
comes from the unknown risks of consuming a good. In the case of drugs and drug-like
products we can see large systematic errors by consumers who are harmed as a
result. For example, the American Medical Association and doctors, as well as
the US government, helped promote cigarette smoking, increasing the number of
smokers and cigarettes smoked, and thereby increased the amount of lung cancer
and heart disease.[6]
Systematic errors in the case here are the choices
made about pharmaceutical drugs where the physical or psychological harm are
not properly anticipated because of the FDA's seal of approval. This would
include the use of these drugs as prescribed by doctors, as well as the illegal
use by those not under medical supervision. In recent years the harm from
prescription drugs has caught up with and surpassed the harm from illegal
drugs. This suggests that more people perceive prescription drugs to be far
safer than their black-market counterparts.
By 2008, more than half of the overdose deaths (55 percent)
were related to prescription drugs. Opiate pain relievers such as Oxycontin
accounted for 73 percent of prescription-related deaths. Additionally, in 2009
there were 1.2 million emergency-room visits related to prescription-drug
overdose, compared to 1 million related to illegal drugs such as heroin and
cocaine.[7]
The link between antidepressant drugs and teen suicide
is murky and the research seems inconclusive, but this is typically the case
with FDA-approved drugs. The drug companies conduct tests that are reviewed by
the FDA, but what really counts as "safe and effective" is illusive
for the ultimate consumer and even the doctors who are doing the prescribing.
Despite inconclusive evidence, an FDA advisory panel recommended a "black
box" warning for all antidepressants. This is most the most serious action
taken by the FDA short of outright prohibition.
The determination of what drugs are safe and effective
in the free market would be more open, with greater oversight and review, and
subject to third-party approval. We could well imagine that something similar
to Consumer Reports or Underwriters Laboratories would emerge to provide a more
dependable seal of approval.
Economic Categories of Drugs
In order to make some sense of this FDA-caused chaos
let us organize our economic analysis on the basis of economic categories,
rather than the chemical or governmental classifications of drugs. As described
above, drugs can be classified as good, bad, or ugly. For example,
"good" drugs include those that arose on the free market and continue
to be produced, distributed, and consumed on the market without
product-specific government interventions.
Examples for this category include aspirin, milk of
magnesia, Preparation H, and laudanum (i.e., tincture of opium). These drugs
are characterized as high benefit, low cost, and little "harm" as
described above. This category would also include the large markets for alcohol
(i.e., beer, wine, and spirits), marijuana, and tobacco, except that in recent
decades these markets have experienced massive government intervention in the
United States. Otherwise, these markets would be characterized as high benefit,
low cost, and low harm.[8]
The "bad" category of drugs includes those
where the free market was replaced by government prohibition and the black
market. Examples of this category include crack cocaine, crystal
methamphetamine, heroin, and the hand-sanitizer martini. These markets are
characterized by low benefit, high cost, and a great deal of harm. It is
important to note that some of the "harm" associated with these drugs
is "expected" in the sense that they are known to be dangerous.[9]
It is also worthy of note that if these drugs were
placed in a "good" environment (i.e., the market) the harm would
decrease, the cost would dramatically decrease, and the benefits would dramatically
increase. For example, the Bayer pharmaceutical company sold a low-potency,
pharmaceutical, pure dose of heroin in pill form that could even be prescribed
for infants, although it was still highly addictive. Coca-Cola sold millions of
units of its original formula with cocaine as the active ingredient.
The "ugly" category consists of
pharmaceutical drugs developed and governed under the regime of the Food and
Drug Administration.
The bad and ugly categories are obviously inferior to
the "good" category but the judgment as to which one is worse will be
withheld for the time being. Rather, the terms should be understood as
descriptions of the drugs' environment and the types and sources of harm they
bring to consumers.
Bad drugs are those with known inferiorities and
hazards. Efforts to suppress such drugs only serve to make them even more
inferior and hazardous. For example, with increased prohibition penalties,
drugs could have fewer attributes that consumers desire; they could become more
potent and contain more harmful impurities. Stricter prohibition therefore
reduces quality, increases potency, and makes drugs more toxic and potentially
more addictive. Therefore, for our purposes, bad drugs are controlled by
economic laws that dictate more or less predictable responses from
entrepreneurs operating under black-market conditions.
Ugly drugs are controlled less by economic laws and
are more the result of a bureaucratic process. Bureaucracies are driven by
rules that are politically determined, although results are certainly
influenced by the incentive of bureaucrats. The results of this
bureaucratic process appear to us as both mechanical in terms of process and
arbitrary in terms of results. In other words, things get ugly in the realm of the FDA.
It has already been well established that there are
major problems with the FDA's control over pharmaceutical drugs. First, they do
not completely prevent the introduction of harmful products into the market
(although they are biased in that direction and away from allowing beneficial
products into the market). Second, they raise the
cost of bringing new drugs to market, thereby increasing prices and preventing
beneficial products from coming to market. Third, they delay beneficial
products from coming to market for lengthy periods of time. This means that
sick people suffer more and die more often as a result. Fourth, they prohibit
niche drugs that treat rare conditions from coming to market because the high
costs and uncertainties of the FDA's drug-testing process cannot be
sufficiently distributed among such a small group of patients.
The focus here is not that the FDA approves highly dangerous
drugs like thalidomide, or that it stymies the introduction of safe and
effective drugs. The focus here is that FDA approval itself makes drugs more
dangerous. FDA approval creates a type of moral hazard for drug companies,
doctors, and consumers.
A moral hazard causes increased risky behavior to take
place. For example, insurance can create a moral hazard if it induces the
insured party to take on more risks or fewer precautions. Mobile-phone owners,
for example, who purchase insurance on their phone, may be more likely to take
the phones into dangerous situations (e.g., the beach) or to take fewer
precautions (e.g., not using a protective case).
In the case of FDA-approved drugs, consumers take on
increased risks; however, they are not insured against risk,
they are assured against risk. The FDA assumes no financial
responsibility to consumers. When they collect big fines from drug companies,
consumers are not compensated. If the FDA has approved a drug as safe and
effective, why should consumers think otherwise? When doctors prescribe these
drugs, how are patients supposed to react? They are at a tremendous
disadvantage in terms of information. Therefore, it is quite natural for
consumers to let down their guard. "Just take your Lipitor and let's go to
KFC!"
Most FDA-approved drugs have side effects; many have
dangerous side effects, some of which are deadly. Taking more than one drug at
a time also introduces the possibility of dangerous drug interactions. Many
drugs are not effective for the entire population and many drugs do not pass
any kind of cost-benefit analysis. Particularly disturbing is that FDA approval
helps shield pharmaceutical companies from liability resulting from damages.
They are not exempt from liability, but the fact that the FDA approves of both
the drug and its labeling makes it difficult to sue drug companies.
However, the most serious problem might be that people
rely on FDA-approved drugs rather than applying more straightforward means of
addressing health issues, such as lifestyle changes.
Many health concerns like high blood pressure, high
cholesterol, heart disease, and type-2 diabetes can be addressed by changes in
nutrition, exercise and environment. Even cancer, liver disease, and arthritis
can be addressed with these lifestyle changes, although obviously not
completely. This is where prescription drugs actually should come into play.
The lifestyle method has the tremendous advantage of
not just solving the initial health problem but also of helping to prevent
future problems. For example, losing weight to address a blood pressure or
cholesterol problem also helps reduce the risk of developing heart disease.
Rather than be responsible for their own healthcare,
American consumers have become passive absorbers of healthcare services and
products. Worse yet, if they have comprehensive insurance and low copays, they
become immune to price as a deterrent. The result is overconsumption of
dangerous products. As drugs substitute for healthy lifestyles, healthcare, or
rather "health" continues to decline, and hence the high cost of
healthcare in America.
The high cost of healthcare is one of the most
significant economic problems in the United States. We may have produced what
is considered a "high quality" system, but it has not resulted in
quality health. In 2010 there were almost 4 billion prescriptions written or
more than 12 prescriptions for every man, woman, and child in the country. The
moral hazard of FDA approval is exacerbated by insurance, in the sense that
less than 7 percent of prescriptions are paid by cash, and copays have fallen
to an average of $10, making drugs a cheap substitute for lifestyle changes.[10]
The Pure Food and Drug Act of 1906 was supposed to
make our food "pure" and to eliminate those so-called poisonous
"patented" medicine products. The FDA was established to accomplish
those goals. What they have achieved is a population that eats poisonous food
and gobbles down tons of patented medicines.
Notes
[1] The FDA approval process represents a
government-created moral hazard and is a violation of the common law doctrine
of procedural unconscionability. This doctrine applies to
processes that are so one-sided, unfair, and harmful that enforcement would
violate the conscience of the court. Courts are very averse to invoking the
doctrine of unconscionability in civil cases because the grounds for doing so
are vague. Invoking the doctrine in civil cases does itself create a moral
hazard because people are not responsible for their actions in similar
circumstances. Libertarians are generally opposed to the use of this doctrine
and consider it outside the law. However, it is part of the common law and
could prove quite useful against government activities if government courts
were willing to take on such cases as the FDA approval process or state
lotteries.
[4] Authorities have yet to solve the Chicago
Tylenol murders of 1982 and the FDA has failed to adequately warn the general
public of the dangers of non-adulterated Tylenol and other pain medication.
[5] "Collusion
Between Pharmaceutical Industry and Government Deepens," Mercola.com, August 2,
2012.
[6] "What the
American Medical Association hopes you never learn about its true
history," NaturalNews.com, June 23, 2005.
[7] "Vital Signs: Overdoses of
Prescription Opioid Pain Relievers — United States, 1999–2008," Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report November 4,
2011 / 60(43);1487-1492.
[8] Harm can rise precipitously because of
government intervention. For example, government ownership and management of
roads has led to a disastrously high number of automobile accidents involving
alcohol consumption and other drugs.
[9] This "expected harm" is the harm
experienced by consumers who were fully aware of the risks and took them
anyway. Such individuals are extremely high-time-preference individuals, and so
the harm should not be fully attributed to the drug or the prohibition but
rather to this type of problematic individual.
[10] "The Use of Medicines in the United States:
Review of 2011," IMS Institute for Health Infomatics, April 2012.
No comments:
Post a Comment