For the most part the general
public has distinct and sometimes divergent views on the Federal Reserve and
the European Central Bank (ECB). Obviously, there are political and
institutional differences that present both with unique challenges, meaning
that what constraints apply to the Fed do not always apply to the ECB and vice
versa. It certainly seems that way on the surface when the ECB pledges to buy
an unlimited amount of troubled sovereign bonds to keep those nations from
plunging into the Greek abyss, while at nearly the exact same moment the US
central bank pledges to buy an unlimited amount of erstwhile untroubled mortgage
products to theoretically create jobs.
Despite the operational
idiosyncrasies of each central bank, they are entangled by something far more
pivotal: operative theory. What I mean by operative theory here goes deeper
than just their now-constant appeal to debasement. For all intents and
purposes, global central banks view "money" as nothing more than
"charta", a Latin word for "token".
The word itself is more
meaningful than just its Latin etymology. In the early part of the 20th
century, there was a school of thought advocating a full fiat system where
money was nothing more than a creature of government whim. Through the power of
taxation a government can essentially create currency or money from anything it
wished: if government accepts sea shells as payment for taxes, sea shells
become fiat money. In theoretical terms, if the government tomorrow declared
this to be the case, suddenly sea shells have been given "value"
through the creation of coercive demand enforced at the point of the figurative
government gun.
Earlier this week, Andrea
Enria, Chairman of the European Union's banking regulator, the European Banking
Authority (EBA), was quoted by Bloomberg congratulating the banking system's
continued revival and renewal:
"We want banks to hold on to and keep building capital. The key positive in the response of banks to this exercise is that 75 percent of the shortfall was raised by retaining earnings and other measures -- fresh capital."
There is more than just a
rhetorical sleight of hand going on here. That statement may seem
uncontroversial on its face since it is technically accurate in the accounting
sense, but semantically the word "capital", which is the central
focus, has a broader meaning than the generic application used by Mr. Enria.
It is absolutely true that
European banks have increased their capital levels by about €200 billion since
the mid-2011 stress tests, and have done so largely through retained earnings
and "fresh capital". But that connotes successful business practices
being applied on a systemic scale, where banks throughout the European
continent have been swiftly rewarded for their business and market acumen. Yet,
we know that to be an outright falsehood given the constant state of market
upheaval and near-permanent monetary interventions, so how do we square the
technically true accounting statement with the obvious market rejection of
large proportions of European banking?
Into that void delves charta.
Fresh capital in the modern monetary sense is a unit on an accounting
statement, devoid of any larger connotation. For investors and the process of
investing, however, accounting should have meaning - where a business gets its
money matters greatly in the process of investment analysis. Since banks are
nothing more than businesses in the intermediation industry, we rightfully
expect "capital" success to have such positive meaning.
Perhaps the best example of
this divergence in meaning is seen in the oldest banking concern in the world.
Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena SpA was in existence before Christopher
Columbus sailed backward for India. The bank is commonly described as having
survived ages of social upheavals, wars and Acts of God, but it may not survive
the age of central bank activism having received bailouts in both 2009 and
2012.
Monte Paschi has been losing
money due to a distinct lack of business acumen - first in investing far
outside its comfort zone while trying to become a multi-regional bank on par
with UniCredit and Intesa (the two largest banks in Italy, and two banks that
are also routinely cited as systemic problems). That meant an aggressive
expansion through mergers and acquisitions where bank "capital" was
deployed in the purchase of other banks and their intermediary artifacts.
Efficiently deploying capital requires paying a "good" price for
"good" assets.
The bank lost €4.7 billion in
2011, in large part due to writedowns on goodwill created by that unwise
capital deployment. In 2007, for example, Monte Paschi bought Banca
Antonveneta, another Italian concern that has been a dead weight, loss-producer
nearly from the moment the deal closed. Because of the hefty premium the bank
paid, creating the accounting ledger of goodwill, these writedowns of goodwill
flowed onto the income statement as losses, thus effectively destroying that
deployed "capital" or "money".
Destruction of capital has
been acute at Monte Paschi in 2012, moreso than perhaps any other bank outside
of Spain. When told by the EBA to raise "fresh capital" of at least
€3.27 billion earlier this year, the bank found it had no access to it, and not
for lack of trying. Apparently, market investors have determined that Monte
Paschi is not a good intermediary of money and found it undeserving of fresh
money injections that would satisfy the accounting notion of capital.
Without prospects for capital,
Monte Paschi was "forced" into Tremonti bond sales with the Italian
federal government. Facing a June 30 deadline imposed by the EBA, the Italian
government first capped its purchase of these bonds at €2 billion, but as with
so many things about political interventions (money is meaningless, after all),
by August 23, the total was increased to €3.4 billion. Tremonti bonds are a
special class, amounting to a hybrid security that is both debt and equity,
thus qualifying to be treated as "capital" for the accounting
statements. These bonds require the bank to pay the Italian government
somewhere above 8.5% interest in any profitable years. In any year where the
bank loses "money" in the course of normal operation, the bonds
convert into equity - at book value! In other words, the Italian government
will be covering the bank's future losses on past lending at about five times
the current market price of the company's stock.
But unbridled expansion
ambitions have not been the only source of negative capital for Monte Paschi.
According to the Washington Post, the bank's chief executive, Fabrizio Viola,
said last month that, "The problem of Monte Paschi was the fact that over
the last two years, they invested a lot, in my opinion too much, in the
government portfolio," before adding, "It was not a prudent
decision." While this speaks to the lack of business acumen in operating a
business that is supposed to create positive capital, it also squares the
charta circle.
The bank is being rescued by a
government in which it loses "money" by investing in that same
government. Worse, the "capital" provided by the government is
essentially provided by "money" invested by the bank itself through
all those bond purchases (by last estimate, Monte Paschi had about €25 billion
in Italian sovereign bonds on its balance sheet). This is all well and good,
fully satisfying the requirements of all the accounting and national banking
regulations in existence. There is nothing illegal here, no statutory fraud nor
impropriety. Charta really is the meaningless accumulation of units of account,
regardless of source.
This theoretical application
in the case of Monte Paschi is by no means unique. While these accounting
details are not widespread, the charta infestation has become endemic on a
systemic level. And while Monte Paschi exemplifies some of the "fresh
capital" that Mr. Enria alluded to, those retained earnings are certainly
more problematic. For the most part, capital obtained by retained earnings has
been built on the back of ultra-low interest rates created by the ECB's
monetary injections. A good portion of European banks, particularly the larger
"core" banks, enjoy the privilege of near-zero (in the case of normal
monetary operations), low-cost extended maturity (in the case of the LTRO's)
and favorably priced (in the case of the SMP) "money" that was
created by nothing more than the digital account expressions of expanding the
ECB balance sheet.
Of course ultra-low interest
rates are not unique to Europe as the United States has been under the thumb of
ZIRP for nearly four years - with another three already planned and
communicated. Ben Bernanke himself earlier this week addressed the rebuild of
retained earnings in the United States through ZIRP. Perhaps far more explicit
than the ECB, the Fed Chairman was essentially arguing that increasing the
number of charta directly increases the number of employed Americans, therefore
providing some purpose to the government monopoly of money.
The full context of that
argument, however, argues that "money" is far more meaningful than
just the government's imprimatur or eligibility for taxation extinguishment. In
addressing ZIRP, Chairman Bernanke acknowledged the flipside of rebuilding the
banking system's collective retained earnings:
"My colleagues and I know that people who rely on investments that pay a fixed interest rate, such as certificates of deposit, are receiving very low returns, a situation that has involved significant hardship for some.
However, I would encourage you to remember that the current low levels of interest rates, while in the first instance a reflection of the Federal Reserve's monetary policy, are in a larger sense the result of the recent financial crisis, the worst shock to this nation's financial system since the 1930s. Interest rates are low throughout the developed world, except in countries experiencing fiscal crises, as central banks and other policymakers try to cope with continuing financial strains and weak economic conditions.
A second observation is that savers often wear many economic hats. Many savers are also homeowners; indeed, a family's home may be its most important financial asset. Many savers are working, or would like to be. Some savers own businesses, and--through pension funds and 401(k) accounts--they often own stocks and other assets. The crisis and recession have led to very low interest rates, it is true, but these events have also destroyed jobs, hamstrung economic growth, and led to sharp declines in the values of many homes and businesses. What can be done to address all of these concerns simultaneously? The best and most comprehensive solution is to find ways to a stronger economy. Only a strong economy can create higher asset values and sustainably good returns for savers."
Forget that second paragraph
where the Chairman essentially blames George Bush (or at least that he believes
the stain of 2008 continues to haunt the real economy four years later) and
then commits the logical fallacy of "everybody else is doing it".
What is the meat of his argument is the third paragraph, that low interest
rates are the only way to achieve a "stronger economy", and by extension,
the only way for interest rates, and thus the returns on money and real
savings, to eventually rise again. Because ZIRP is only achieved through
increasing the number of monetary units, connecting the logical dots here, the
only way to get a strong economy and "normal" returns on savings
capital is through charta ideology. Savers of real capital have no choice but
to suffer in the backdoor socializing of bank losses in order for the economy
to recover - though the suffering is real to date, the recover part is
conspicuously absent.
This philosophy thoroughly
upends capitalism. The entire premise of capitalism is the efficient deployment
of capital; capital having full meaning absent in the sense of modern money.
Capitalists create capital through successful deployment of "money",
turning that "money" into true wealth of productive enterprise. That
successful deployment of money creates additional capital that can be
"monetized" in asset markets, but the number of new monetary units
has no basis in trying to predict or determine successful business acumen. That
is the traditional role of intermediation.
Chartalism in this form is
nothing more than a theory that capital can easily be replaced by mere monetary
units, as if there is no information content relevant to economic efficiency
stored in the flow of capitalized money. Past success in the form of stored
"earnings" or "money" is, following this line of inquiry,
eminently replaceable by determined government planning. In that way, money is
now flowed or channeled on the basis of poor past performance rather than on
the basis of good expected future performance.
In the past four years,
central banks have attempted to resurrect economic health by adding new charta
to the system with perfect exclusivity biased to institutions and businesses
that have destroyed their past stores of capital, despite the very visible fact
that said destruction of capital is the quintessential measure of real economy
inefficiency. If the destruction of money has meaning, then so does the
creation of money, or at least the methodology of determining how money is
acquired. Bernanke's theory, shared by all the major central banks on this
globe, is that economies can only recover when capital is disadvantaged in
favor of meaningless money. This is not just the theory he espouses in public
speeches, it is the operative theory put in practice by central banks in every
major economy.
The primacy of meaningless
money is such that the entire system of savers, the majority of which have
created actual capital and acquired value, need to be hamstrung by ZIRP in
favor of institutions that destroyed real capital in the inefficient pursuit of
the very policies that central banks directed in the first place. Success is to
be shunned and disfavored in the socialized and institutionalized process of
debt creation from the very firms that have proven beyond a doubt that they are
not capable of maintaining economic efficiency. The ascendancy of chartalism is
the only manner in which such a backward system could actually exist.
Unfortunately, real economies
run not on meaningless money, but on sustainable and efficient success. All of
these banks and central banks need to emulate the ideals cleverly conjured and
portrayed in the Smith Barney TV commercials of decades past, when firms used
to "earn" their money. The capital on a bank's balance sheet at one
time (before fiat money and transcontinental wholesale money markets) denoted
success at intermediating the pool of savings, turning past success into
additional future success in a virtuous circle that is the hallmark of every
thriving economy in history. In short, money is supposed to be about winners
and losers. Economies need to reward the virtue of economic winners and delete
the societal and systemic cost of the losers. Without monetary meaning, there
is no sorting process of winners and losers; there are only losers that are
supposed to take comfort in the vacuous experimentations of academic central
bankers that passes for progress and evolution.
More than anything, human
nature needs value and meaning in money. Maybe central bankers should try their
hands at investing without any meaning to money and capital - it doesn't work.
Try as they might, particularly with reducing economic agents to mathematical
equations and models, modern mainstream economics has tried to dehumanize the
economic and financial system. It certainly makes economics appear more
scientific, but ultimately that is just the cloak of self-delusion - models are
not science.
Perhaps central banks have re-invented
an achievable means to a healthy economy with meaningless, inhuman tokens, but
the results of the past four years, particularly 2011 and so far in 2012, are
rather conclusive and unambiguous doubts. It's easy to blame fiscal profligacy
for all the current ills, but such bad habits were borne and nurtured by money
without any real meaning in the first place - intermediation removed from its
eponymous task. Chairman Bernanke, Andrea Enria and Mario Draghi would be hard
pressed to know the difference, however, since their accounting arrangements of
all the new tokens make it difficult to discern anything economically
meaningful at all. The word debasement itself is not just a semantic accident;
it literally means to reduce status or esteem - very human concepts. Welcome to
the world where capital, in a still nominally capitalist system, is as pliable
and fictionable as TV advertising.
No comments:
Post a Comment