By James C. W. Ahiakpor
Keynesianism, with its emphasis on aggregate demand
management to promote economic prosperity, has proven to be an abject failure
since 2008 in the United States and elsewhere. President George W. Bush’s tax
cuts in 2008 and the subsequent bailout of investment banks before President
Barack Obama took office were in the Keynesian mold of promoting spending to
sustain economic activity. President Obama’s various forms of stimulus
expenditures were similarly motivated, and they have not produced the promised
results. Ignoring the evidence, adherents of Lord Keynes’s view of how an
economy works have changed their language from touting the virtues of economic
stimulus to posing a false choice between austerity budgets and economic
growth.
Such change of language
apparently was influential in the last presidential election in France, when
Nicolas Sarkozy lost to socialist Francois Hollande, who touted the virtue of
growth promotion over austerity, or fiscal discipline. The same false choice
was touted in the June Greek elections but without a decisive victory for the
socialist growth promoters. The contrast between government budgetary
discipline and economic growth promotion through increased government spending
is sure to become pronounced in the U.S. election campaign. That is why the
meaninglessness of the alleged alternatives needs to be exposed: Austerity
budgets are the logical means of restoring economic growth; austerity and
growth promotion are not alternatives. The failure of governments to promote
robust economic recovery since the “Great Recession” will persist if a majority
of the voting public is lured into thinking that voting against austerity is a
vote for economic growth.
The key to understanding the
falsehood of contrasting austerity budgets with promotion of economic growth is
simple enough. First, whatever a government spends, it must first take from
taxpayers and buyers of its bonds. Thus unless a government borrows from
nonresidents or the country’s central bank, there is merely a one-to-one substitution
in spending between the private sector and the government sector. Contrary to
Keynesian mythology, therefore, increased government spending, whether financed
by higher taxes or borrowing from domestic residents, does not change total
spending, or so-called aggregate demand. By the same token, decreased
government spending does not reduce total spending. Whatever the government
does not take from the public to spend is retained to be spent by the taxpayers
or the potential government bond purchasers.
Second, individuals are far
better at managing their own funds or investments (out of savings) than
government bureaucrats entrusted with spending tax dollars or funds collected
from the sale of government bonds. Thus even though increased government spending
does not change total spending when funded with tax dollars or domestically
borrowed funds, it increases the share of total income or gross domestic
product (GDP) entrusted to government bureaucrats and decreases the efficiency
of the economy’s functioning and its growth. Austerity—that is, cutting
government spending—particularly when revenue collection has decreased, is thus
the rational path to reducing the inefficiency drag that most government
spending has on an economy.
The Multiplier
Laid-off government workers
may not find alternative employment quickly in a recession; their lot may
improve, however, with the economy’s recovery. The same applies to laid-off
workers in the private sector. Recovery will occur when private-sector economic
activity picks up—with producers anticipating demand for goods and services and
hiring workers to meet that anticipated demand.
But this is where Keynes’s
adherents place the proverbial cart before the horse. By reasoning that
employers must first anticipate demand before they hire workers, they think one
must also accept that government’s appropriating funds to pay its workers
(rather than laying them off) would promote private business activity—the
Keynesian multiplier effect. But, as already pointed out, when government
appropriates funds it merely displaces private-sector spending. The failure of
the $787 billion stimulus from 2009, 2010’s Cash for Clunkers program, mortgage
subsidies, the extension of unemployment benefits, and other doling out of
funds by the Obama administration to stimulate aggregate demand and increase
national income by a factor of 1.5 (according to the logic of Christina Romer
and her colleagues on the Council of Economic Advisers)—all of these attest to
the fundamental error of Keynesian thinking.
How To Grow an Economy
In a 1755 lecture Adam Smith
explained that “Little else is requisite to carry a state to the highest degree
of opulence from the lowest barbarism but peace, easy taxes, and a tolerable
administration of justice: all the rest being brought about by the natural
course of things.” Smith’s “natural course of things” refers to the pursuit of
economic activity in the private sector out of individuals’ self-love, or
self-interest. Such pursuit, Smith also notes in The Wealth of Nations, is driven by “the desire of
bettering our condition, a desire which, though generally calm and
dispassionate, comes with us from the womb, and never leaves us till we go to
the grave.” But thanks to the arrogance (or ignorance) of Keynes and his followers,
the loudest among whom in the United States these days are Paul Krugman and
Robert Reich, we now have people claiming that governments can promote economic
growth directly through increased spending rather than merely creating a
conducive environment for private enterprise to thrive. We’ve come so far in
this version of what Smith described as “folly and presumption,” or “conceit,”
that politicians talk about “growing” the economy as if they were farmers
planting crops.
Were government budgetary allocations
the best way to promote economic prosperity, the economies of the defunct
Soviet Union and Maoist China would be the models for the world.
It is time the Keynesians
recognized their failures and spared humanity the prolonged agony of economic
malfunctioning—anemic growth or contractions and continued high unemployment.
Budgetary austerity is not an alternative to economic growth promotion but the
rational path to it.
No comments:
Post a Comment