A return to sound money
by John P. Cochran
Austrian economists have, since the latest boom-bust
cycle and financial crisis, called for a critical reexamination of the "rationale of central
banking" by emphasizing the role of central banking in
generating business cycles. The argument is well summarized by Roger Garrison:
The decentralization of money, as proposed by Hayek (1976) and
explored by Selgin and White
(1994), has an increasing strong claim on our attention.
Concerns with political feasibility should be separated from the more
fundamental reconsideration of a market based money supply. In light of our
continuing experience with a bubble-prone central bank, we might well
anticipate that a comparative-institutions analysis would favor a market
solution to our money and credit problems. At the very least, a better
understanding of the workings of a decentralized monetary system would help identify
the perils and pitfalls of continued centralization. ("Interest-Rate
Targeting during the Great Moderation: A Reappraisal," p. 199, links
added)
Thanks to Congressman Ron Paul's strong
interest in a market-based money, Austrian
economists have had the opportunity to argue in favor of abolishing central
banks and for a decentralization or denationalization of money in testimony
before Congressional committees. (For examples see Salerno, White, and Cochran here, Ebeling here, and Herbener
and Klein here.)
Gerald P. O'Driscoll provides more background and
raises issues and concerns in an important new working paper at The Cato
Institute, "Central Banks: Abolish
or Reform?" He cautions,
Plans to abolish central banks constitute an extreme reform. It is doubtful that such plans can succeed without broader institutional change, occurring either first or simultaneously. That is likely true regardless of the strength of evidence on central bank performance. (p. 2)
O'Driscoll concludes,
We have two bad systems: the fiscal and the monetary. They are intertwined now as they were in the 18th and 19th centuries. They must be reformed, or together they will destroy the economic system that sustains them. They have become parasitical. The unsettled question is whether anything less than radical reform of both will work. Can central banks be constrained to a Bagehot‐like role, or must they be abolished? Can a "bad system" be made better, or do we need wholesale replacement? That is the question that monetary economists should be discussing. (p. 30, links added).
While most Austrians favor replacing central banking
with a market-based decentralized money, most mainstream economists opposed to
broadly discretionary monetary policy favor rules to restrain central bankers'
actions, not abolishment of central banking. As examples, John B. Taylor
strongly defends rule-based reforms, while Scott Sumner and market monetarists recommendnominal GDP targeting. However, some
economists are clearly beginning to recognize, as most Austrians have, that
central banks are or are becoming dangerous financial
central planners.
Hayek, in his writings in the 1970s, made
recommendations on how central bankers could "best" function while
also arguing ultimately for the elimination of central banking. He thus argued,
given the widespread existence of central banks and the general acceptance of
active monetary policy, which was heavily influenced by a Keynesian economic
macro framework, the best policy in this environment was that "Though
monetary policy must prevent wide fluctuations in the quantity of money or the
volume of the income stream … the primary aim must again become
stability of the value of money." To paraphrase, in normal
times there is a need to, a la Friedman
or Taylor, have a more or less automatic monetary framework, but if policy
still generated boom-bust cycles, then to prevent "liquidity crisis or
panics" there is a need "to ensure convertibility of all kinds of
near-money into real money." For this, "the monetary authority must
be given some discretion" (Hayek 1979, p. 18). But because
he recognized the strong interconnection between monetary and fiscal policy
that would threaten long-term economic stability, Hayek strongly favored a denationalization of
money. As quoted in Pizano, Hayek reflected,
I do not believe that we would have major industrial fluctuations if it were not for the present banking system, which in turn depends on the government monopoly of the supply of money. I have been driven into proposing the denationalization of money. (Conversations with Great Economists, p. 10)
He continues:
Anyhow, depressions are not the result of the operation of the market. They are the result of government control, particularly in the sphere of monetary policy.
A related issue, of interest to Austrian economists,
raised in debates by proponents of reform, centers on whether the Fed
contributed to the recent crisis by keeping interest rates too low for too long
from 2003 to 2005. Much of the discussion was triggered by John B. Taylor's
March 31 "Policy Failure and the
Great Recession." A review of the discussion should reinforce
how important and useful Austrian insights are for properly
interpreting causes of the current crisis, as argued by Garrison and Cochran, and in guiding
discussions of appropriate ways to reform monetary institutions, if a goal is
to make such crises less likely in the future.
Taylor used his interpretation of Robert Hetzel (The Great Recession:
Market Failure or Policy Failure?) as platform to
attempt to bolster his positions that (1) rules are preferred to discretion,
and (2) excessive discretion allowed the monetary authorities to make two
significant policy errors during the Greenspan/Bernanke watch; interest rates were too low for too long in 2003–05 leading to a
boom and a necessary consequent bust and the subsequent bust
was compounded and/or triggered by interest rates being too high in 2007–08.
While the point that the Fed moved rates too high in 2007–08 does not appear to
be controversial among economists who favor rules over abolishing a central
bank, many commentators, especially supporters of nominal GNP targeting, strongly reject the rates-too-low-for-too-long argument.
Defenders of the Fed policy circa 2003–05 argue, contraAustrians and Taylor,
that, since Fed policy did not lead to either significant price inflation or
significant increases in inflationary expectations, the policy generated no
problems for the economy. For them, but often also for Taylor, major policy-induced
problems for the economy areFriedman plucks, policy errors
that create too much money and credit constraint, triggering a recession as the
economy performs temporarily below
potential.
Taylor has the key element essentially correct: rates were too low for too long. But working from a
highly aggregated model, Taylor has no really adequate response to his critics.
He is forced to rely on rhetoric and historical interpretation of Fed actions
during the relevant period of time. Taylor relies on his reading of Hetzel, who
in general defends Fed policy in 2003–05, but per Taylor, Hetzel provides evidence
for the too-low-for-too-long policy error when he argues,
In 2003–2004, the Greenspan FOMC did make a decision
that would later have enormous implications. At this time, The FOMC backed off
its long-run objective of returning to price stability and instead adopted an
ill-defined objective of positive inflation.
Thus for Taylor, as for Austrian critics of Fed
policy, "there is a clear connection between the too easy period and the
too tight period"; and to stress the importance of this, Taylor adds,
"I have emphasized the 'too low for too long' period in my writing because
of its 'enormous implications' (to use Hetzel's description) for the crisis and
recession which followed."
Taylor, unlike his critics, who see the only errors by
the Fed as the "Great Moderation ended as being too tight right before the
bust," recognizes, as do the Austrians, that the "Fed's action in
2003–2005 should be considered as possible part of the problem." Too bad
he is unfamiliar with or unwilling to use Austrian analysis to support his
position relative to 2003–2005. Austrian monetary theory and business-cycle
theory provide a much better understanding of why a monetary-policy-driven
credit expansion, such as the 2003–04 period, fuels a boom-bust cycle in a no-
or low-inflation environment and, as Ravier, in "Rethinking Capital-Based
Macroeconomics" (pp. 367–371), explains
in detail, even if the policy is intended to speed recovery from a recession.
Cochran ("Hayek and the 21st Century Boom-Bust
and Recession-Recovery") argues the
macroeconomic developments in the US economy from 1995 to present cannot be
understood without a reference to a capital-structure-based macroeconomic
framework. There were, in fact, back-to-back policy-driven boom-bust cycles.
The first boom-bust of the period, 1995–2000, should have provided evidence
that even with stable prices or low inflation, distortions in the structure of
production caused by money and credit creation can create significant
coordination problems in a growing economy. The monetary growth which
accommodated a productivity shock generated a boom with a high-tech bubble. The
resulting "bust," at least measured in terms of the cycle impact on
GDP, was relatively mild. The significance of this cycle for the role of monetary
policy was perhaps missed because it occurred at the end of the "Great Moderation." This
period was a time of better policy — at least compared to monetary policy of
the 1960s and 1970s — but, as discussed byGarrison (2009), not
necessarily good policy. During this period, central banks were heavily
influenced by macroeconomic events of the 1970s that seemed to discredit the
neoclassical synthesis/Keynesian consensus. A vast economic literature from the
consequent policy-effectiveness debate emphasized central-bank policies that —
at least in the long run — aimed, much like Hayek had recommended, at price
stabilization as a dominant policy goal. The Fed, while not explicitly
inflation targeting, followed a policy that mimicked a Taylor-rule policy. Garrison
(2009, p. 187) characterizes this as a "learning by doing policy"
which, based on events post-2003, would be better classified as "so far so
good" or "whistling in the dark."
The actual result of this "learning by doing
policy" is described by Garrison in "Natural Rates of Interest and
Sustainable Growth":
In the earlier episode, the Federal Reserve moved to
counter the upward pressure of interest rates, causing actual interest rates
not to deviate greatly from the historical norm. In the later episode, the
Federal Reserve moved to reinforce the downward pressure on interest rates,
causing the actual interest rates to be exceedingly low relative to the
historical norm. Although the judgment, made retrospectively by economists of
virtually all stripes, that the Fed funds target rate was "too low for too
long" between mid-2003 and mid-2004, it was almost surely too low for too
long relative to the natural rate in both episodes. (p. 433)
Thus the mildness of the first recession of the 21st
century was followed by a relatively slow, jobless recovery. This led many
economists and pundits to encourage the Fed to re-inflate — create another boom
or bubble — to ignite growth and employment. Taylor is right: the Fed
accommodated the requests leading to, as argued by Austrians and by Taylor in
2008, "a boom and an inevitable bust"
(emphasis mine). The
resulting housing-bubble-led boom-bust was a classic misdirection of production
driven by monetary stimulus of an economy operating below potential. Far from
being beneficial or at best benign, this attempt to use monetary policy to
reduce unemployment in the short run did, as predicted by Hayek (1979, p. 11),
become a cause of "more unemployment
than the amount it was originally designed to prevent." From about 2005 to
late 2007, the economy appeared healthy, and, at least temporarily, growth
returned to its potential GDP growth path. As the end of the housing bubble
clearly illustrated, and as many Austrian had
predicted, the health was only apparent.
Responses to Taylor by David Glasner, Marcus Nunes at
Historinhas, or Scott Sumner focus on
how a central bank in a fiat-money system can do "better policy." A
better understanding of the cause of crisis based on an Austrian
capital-structure-based macroeconomics should shift the focus away from rules
versus discretion to the more fundamental question raised most recently by
O'Driscoll, echoing Hayek: are there monetary institutions that could generate
consistently better economic outcomes? Research by Selgin, Lastrapes, and
White strongly suggest that conclusion should be yes:
Some proposed alternative arrangements might plausibly
do better than the Fed as presently constituted. We conclude that the need for
a systematic exploration of alternatives to the established monetary system is
… pressing today.
Central-bank response to the most recent crisis makes
the discussion for abolishing the Fed even more important. The Fed has moved in
the direction of greater, not lesser, central-bank involvement in the economy. John B. Taylor reported
that the Federal Reserve purchased 77 percent of the net increase in the debt
by the federal government in 2011. The Fed's monetary policy is now a "mondustrial policy." It is an
intervention framework financed by money creation. The Fed has done extensively
more in response to this crisis than Hayek's recommended prevention of a
secondary deflation. It has engaged in picking winners and losers — crony
capitalism at its worst. As recognized by John H. Cochrane of the University of
Chicago in "The Federal Reserve:
From Central Bank to Central Planner,"
"The Fed's 'nontraditional' actions have crossed a bright line into fiscal
policy and the direct allocation of credit."
The Great Moderation did represent a period of
improved monetary policy and provides some reason for the optimism of a Taylor
or Sumner that a rules-based reform might restrain a Central bank from becoming
Hummel's gigantic financial central planner. However,
the back-to-back boom-bust cycles that effectively ended the Great Moderation
reinforce Austrian arguments that such a policy would still leave economies
subject to recurring credit-creation-driven booms and the resulting recessions
accompanied by financial crisis. As shown by White, "a gold standard with
free banking would have restrained the boom and bust."
Thus it is even more imperative that Austrians
continue to make as strong a case as possible for a return to sound money. The is why
monetary freedom matters, as it is
ultimately the way forward for an eventual withering away of central banks and
a return to a commodity-based money; a sound
market-based monetary system.
No comments:
Post a Comment