I do not want to waste your time and my energy with
shooting down misguided Keynesian schemes all the time, schemes that have been
refuted long ago and should by now be instantly laughed out of town whenever
put forward. But arch-Keynesian Richard Koo’s latest attempt in the commentary section of the Financial
Times to justify out-of-control deficit spending in
the United States as a smartly designed and necessary policy that will keep
‘aggregate demand’ up and lead to recovery, is making the rounds on the
internet. Koo’s article is a mechanical and naïve exposition of the 101 of
Keynesian stimulus doctrine, clearly aimed at those who still perceive the
economy as a simple equation with Y, C, I and lots of G in it. If private
demand falls out from under the bottom of the economy, it can be replaced with
the government’s demand. Simple.
And wrong, of course.
But the piece is not without some educational value. I
promise this will be shorter than my attack on the new money mysticism at
the IMF.
Fiscal suicide as recovery
strategy
I am not sure if even in Washington there is anybody
left who still seriously claims that $1 trillion-plus deficits year-in and
year-out are anything but a sure-fire sign of a public sector out of control –
a public sector that despite generous and growing staffing levels is simply
running out of fingers to put into the many holes from which the money is
leaking. Yet Richard Koo wants us to believe there is a method to the
recklessness, that this is a finely calibrated strategy to save the economy.
Koo’s story goes like this: The private sector has
overdosed on credit in the preceding boom and is now in the process of balance
sheet repair. Households and corporations are not borrowing, investing and
spending but instead saving and paying down debt. This is sensible and
unavoidable, and not even artificially low rates of zero percent can persuade
them to change their ways and rather borrow and spend. This is where the government
has to step in. It has to borrow the funds that corporations and households
save and pay back to their original creditors, and spend these funds for the
greater good so that ‘aggregate demand’ is kept from collapsing and the economy
from tanking.
Here is Koo:
“[However,] if someone is saving money or paying down debt, someone else must be borrowing and spending that money to keep the economy going. In a normal world, it is the role of interest rates to ensure all saved funds are borrowed and spent, with interest rates rising when there are too many borrowers and falling when there are too few. But when the private sector as a whole is saving money or paying down debt at zero interest rates, the banks cannot lend the repaid debt or newly deposited savings because interest rates cannot go any lower. This means that, if left unattended, the economy will continuously lose aggregate demand equivalent to the unborrowed savings.”
This is evidently wrong. This view neglects the
function of market prices (other than interest rates) and the role of money –
two aspects that Keynesians have a habit of ignoring. Let us go through this
step by step.
Restating Koo’s scenario to
include money-flows and money-balances
If some (or even a considerable number of)
corporations and households use their present money balances or present
money-income to repay debt, this simply means that rather than holding large
money balances themselves or spending their current money-income on investment
goods or consumption goods, this money now flows to the creditors of these
households and corporations, and these creditors now either hold themselves
larger money balances, or they re-invest in investment goods (productive
assets, equities or bonds), or buy consumption goods. Only three options are
logically available to anybody who receives a money-income: keep it in money,
spend it on investment goods or consume it (spend it on consumption goods).
The problem that Koo describes – a drop in ‘aggregate
demand’ – can only materialize if the money-income that households and
corporations received and previously ‘spent’ again on investment goods or
consumption goods (and which thus kept circulating through the economy and
maintained ‘aggregate demand‘), is now no longer spent on investment goods or
on consumption goods because the creditors who now hold this extra money simply
keep it in the form of higher cash balances. If the creditors spent the money
that is being repaid to them again on investment or consumption goods, there
would be no drop in ‘aggregate demand’ – and to the extent that the creditors
lent the funds again to other private-sector borrowers there would, of course,
be no net-deleveraging of the private sector in aggregate. Only if the
creditors decide to keep accumulating money balances rather than channelling
the money income again into consumption and investment will ‘aggregate demand’
drop.
Of course, Koo will maintain that this is very likely
indeed. Interest rates are zero, so the incentive to lend the money again is
low. Additionally, nobody wants to borrow. So the creditors – and this must
include banks, pension funds, insurance companies, in short anybody who has
previously extended credit to households and corporations and now gets repaid –
will likely keep hoarding money. And Koo would maintain that interest rates
cannot fall any further – they are already at zero – so the extra money will
not lead to lower rates and thus encourage extra borrowing.
We can now rephrase Koo’s problem. What happens ‘in
aggregate’ is simply this: economic actors reduce their money-outlays on
non-money goods (investment and consumption goods) and instead accumulate money
balances. But this must mean that, all else being equal, money-prices for
non-money goods decline. The prices of consumption and investment goods fall
and the purchasing power of money rises. This is deflation and is dreaded like
the plague by the Keynesians, but wrongly so, as it is very clear that falling
prices are exactly what will ultimately stop the ‘hoarding of money’ and
encourage spending again – spending on consumption goods and investment goods.
There is no way around the fact that a money-hoarding
public considers the money-prices of non-money goods too high, which is
precisely why the public keeps its wealth in money, and that it is falling
prices that would rectify the situation easily. As the opportunity costs for
holding wealth in the form of money rise with falling prices, the incentive to
spend the money grows.
Koo ignores falling prices as
an essential corrective
Koo only considers interest rates as a mechanism for
keeping the economy in balance. He does not consider the role of other market
prices. Interest rates are indeed important market prices (so important, in
fact, that the central bank should not distort them, and distorting interest
rates systematically – almost always to the downside – is indeed every central
bank’s mission). Interest rates are relative prices. To be precise, they are
the price differential between goods of the same kind at various points in
time. But there are other important relative prices to consider, including
those between different goods at the same time.
If I consider the current price of a good – whether
consumption or investment good – to be too high (to be unsustainably high) I
will not spent my current money balances on this good, and, importantly, I may
not borrow money – not even at zero percent – to buy it. The cost of borrowing
is an important factor in my decision but it is just one factor. I could borrow
the money for free and acquire the good but I would still encounter the risk of
a price drop in whatever I buy with the borrowed money, and it is evidently
that risk that is keeping people in cash at present. If I expect the price to
drop in the future it would be better to not buy now, even if funding costs are
near zero. (As an aside funding costs are hardly zero for most of us at present,
as Koo implies, but this is not important for the argument.)
As we have seen, Koo’s scenario of a drop in
‘aggregate demand’ is only feasible if the desire to hold wealth in the form of
money rather than consumption goods and investment goods is high. People rather
accumulate cash than spend it on investment goods or consumption goods. At
present prices, they prefer money to goods and services.
But hoarding money is a self-correcting process if
(and that is a very big ‘if’ in our complete fiat money system) you allow
prices to fall. At falling prices the opportunity cost of staying in cash
–which gives you great flexibility but does not fulfil any consumption needs
and gives you very meagre returns (just the rate of deflation) – rises
constantly. (To assume that nobody will spend money in a deflationary
environment is nonsense. It ignores ‘time preference’, which is essential to
human action and which also explains why interest is a universal concept. To
want something means, all else being equal, wanting it sooner rather than
later. Current example: Prices of computers and smartphones are falling
constantly yet people spend heavily on these items.)
Consider this example of an
imaginary entrepreneur
An entrepreneur considers buying investment good X,
which would help him realize a certain investment project. The current market
price for X is P, and at this price the investment good promises to provide an
internal rate of return of p. In Koo’s scenario there are plenty of savings
around. So many in fact, that interest rates are zero. The entrepreneur could
borrow for free, acquire X and obtain return p. Why does he not do it? Is his
decision exclusively driven by the level of interest rates? Obviously not. He
may not buy X because he considers P too high and consequently the return p too
low. The investment good is too expensive. The low return of p does not
compensate for all the risks still inherent in the overall investment project
that X would help the entrepreneur realize. If the price P were lower and consequently
the rate of return p higher, then the entrepreneur would invest.
On the surface it may look attractive to buy an equity
portfolio on credit if the loan rate is 1 percent and the dividend yield 3
percent. But you would still not do it if you fear that the equity market is
about to drop by 20 percent.
There is no escaping the fact that if people prefer
holding money to buying non-money goods they consider the prices of non-money
goods too expensive at current prices relative to the monetary asset. In short,
money-prices are too high. This is hardly surprising after the extended
monetary expansion that has caused the over-indebtedness of corporations and
households in the first place. After an inflationary boom prices are too high
and balance sheets overstretched. Importantly, the inflationary boom will not
have lifted all prices to the same extent. Relative prices are also distorted.
At the point of crisis, nobody borrows, everybody
tries to repay debt (or defaults). The creditors accumulate extra cash
balances, partly out of out of concern for the future and partly for lack of
investment opportunities. The inflationary boom turns into a deflationary
correction. Falling prices are now an essential ingredient for stabilizing the
economy. (Again, just as the inflation has not lifted all prices by the same
extent, the deflation will not depress all prices by the same extent. Relative
prices will now re-adjust.) At lower prices, the desire to hoard money will
subside and demand for investment and consumption goods will resurface. Those
who did not participate in the boom but kept their savings and their credit
standing intact and thus their ability to borrow and spend, are now faced with
low interest rates and falling prices. The incentives to put money and credit
to work are substantial. This group will play a crucial role in the recovery.
Absolutely no state intervention is needed.
What I just described is simply the market at work.
Why does this not happen today? Because we live in fiat money system, in a
system of fully elastic money, in which central banks keep printing money to
stop its purchasing power from ever rising and prices from ever declining.
Bizarrely, the central bankers seem to believe they are doing all of us a great
favour. “Look,” they seem to say, “five years into the crisis and prices are
not falling! Hooray, no deflation!” – Yes, and that is precisely the problem.
A personal example
We have lived in London for 16 years and for quite
some time I felt that we could do with a larger apartment or house, given the
size of our family. For years we have been potential buyers of real estate in
London. During the tail end of the recent cheap-money-fuelled housing boom, we
remained on the sidelines. After the bubble burst you might think that this was
now a good opportunity to get into the market. But thanks to zero-interest
rates from the Bank of England, various bank bailouts, quantitative easing, and
other ‘stimulus’ measures, prices have not been falling in many parts of
London, or not by much. Fact is, these policies have kept house prices in many
parts of the country at artificially high levels in my view. In any case, these
policies have certainly not ‘stimulated’ me into putting my own money to work.
Lower prices might have done so – as might have any perception that the bubble
had clearly dissolved, that the market had been allowed to liquidate what was
unsustainable, and that present prices were now ‘real’ uninhibited market
prices. Of course, none of this is the case due to highly interventionist
policies. In the meantime, all the advocates of aggressive monetary stimulus
are high-fiving themselves for having (so far at least) avoided deflation,
having protected the housing market (which means protecting those who borrowed
recklessly in the boom), and saved the banks.
Current monetary policy is prohibiting the liquidation
of imbalances, the correction of prices, the reallocation of resources, the
rebalancing of the economy, and the reinvestment of repaid debt. Monetary
policy is not aiding the recovery, it is obstructing the recovery. What
monetary policy evidently tries to achieve is to create an illusion of recovery
and stability. But nobody in their right mind trusts these prices.
That such a deflationary correction as a free market
would instigate would go on forever, that “the economy will continuously lose
aggregate demand equivalent to the unborrowed savings”, as Koo claims, is
simply nonsense. In an uninhibited market this is impossible.
Stimulating demand – with
higher prices!
But our monetary masters have even crazier ideas. Not
only is any drop in prices and any rise in money’s purchasing power to be
prevented at all cost, prices need to keep rising and this – according to the
logic of our central bank bureaucrats – will then stimulate the economy.
Because all of us are so gullible that we will simply take the phenomenon of
even further rises in nominal prices as an indication that things are fine and
that we need to spend again.
Here is Ben Bernanke, America’s
Printmaster-in-Chief, almost exactly 2 years ago, explaining to the American
public why rising prices of financial assets as a result of the Fed’s policy of
‘quantitative easing’ will help them. I quoted this already on numerous
occasions. Apologies for doing so again but this is such a wonderful exposition
of modern money madness that I keep going back to it. Apologies to Mr. Bernanke
for throwing in some of my own comments.
“This approach (‘quantitative easing’, DS) eased financial conditions in the past and, so far, looks to be effective again (he said this two years ago, DS). Stock prices rose and long-term interest rates fell (bond prices rose, too. DS) when investors began to anticipate the most recent action. Easier financial conditions will promote economic growth. For example, lower mortgage rates will make housing more affordable and allow more homeowners to refinance (but not lead to housing investment if house prices are still too high and still obviously distorted. DS). Lower corporate bond rates (higher bond prices) will encourage investment (well, not in bonds, and it won’t cause corporations to invest, as Richard Koo and I explained above. But here comes the real gem:). And higher stock prices will boost consumer wealth (sic!) and help increase confidence, which can also spur spending.(Emphasis mine, DS.) Increased spending will lead to higher incomes and profits that, in a virtuous circle, will further support economic expansion. (Good luck, Ben. DS)”
So, my imaginary entrepreneur is supposed to be encouraged to invest in X not by a drop in its price but by further rises in its price! And I am supposed to go home to my wife and say, “The crisis is evidently over. Home prices are going up! Come think of it, those London home prices will never fall. They can only ever go up! Let’s take our savings, take out a mortgage and buy now before the Bank of England makes them even more expensive!”
The state makes a mess of
monetary policy – than compounds it with fiscal policy
Back to Richard Koo. The problem he describes will
never occur in a free market. In fact, in a free market with hard money at its
core, it is incredibly unlikely that the type of imbalances that were the
starting point of Koo’s analysis could arise at all. To have large sections of
the economy feel dangerously and hopelessly over-indebted requires the type of
extended credit boom that can only occur in an elastic monetary system with
central banks that can artificially cheapen credit for long stretches of time.
The verdict on our monetary system is devastating: Central banks have actively
encouraged an extended boom in lending and borrowing that has left prices
inflated and distorted, and has left balance sheets overstretched. Now that the
boom is over, even easier monetary policy from the very same central banks is
hindering the dissolution of the distortions and a return to balance.
But is this mess – created by the state with its
mishandling of its money monopoly – now a justification, as Koo claims, for
further state action, now in the form of deficit-spending? Certainly not.
The whole concept of ‘aggregate demand’ assumes that
for the functioning of the economy it does not matter whether demand originates
from the private sector or from the state. It all just adds up to ‘aggregate
demand’, to the statistical whole of GDP. But this is way too simplistic and
mechanical. The economy is not a bucket filled with aggregate demand, and when
some ‘demand’ spills out, we can fill up the bucket again with some other
‘demand’. ‘Demand’ is only ever a homogenous item in the parallel universe of
macroeconomic statistics. A market economy is all about specificdemand,
about the specific use of scarce resources. We are all
participating in this market economy and in the extended network of human
cooperation that only the market economy allows, because each of us has specific goals
and objectives. And if markets are not allowed to operate freely and prices are
not allowed to adjust freely, the resulting distortions are a hindrance to our
attempt to pursue our specific goals.
Whenever government spending is high, it means that
the market’s allocation of resources and the private use of resources are
replaced with bureaucratic allocation of resources and the state’s use of
resources. The grave distortions that are already the result of the state’s
manipulation of money prices and interest rates are further compounded by an
administrative rather than market-driven allocation of scarce means through
fiscal policy.
And is it really feasible that the state would simply
discontinue whatever it started in the crisis to artificially prop up the GDP
statistics once the private sector regained its footing? Would Koo suggest that
the state makes redundant the people it hired during the times of deficit
spending?
Only solution: a return to markets
Keynesians do not trust the market. Allowing prices to
correct, so they claim, would cause never-ending deflationary spirals. This is
without any basis in fact. It is rather their policy of fighting market
imbalances with more intervention and more imbalances that will move the
economy progressively further away from balance and true recovery. Keynesian
policies will keep us in a constant loop of distorted markets and growing
imbalances. They guarantee us a Groundhog Day of economic depression. Until, of
course, patience runs out and the monetary and fiscal overkill – to now
stimulate the economy ‘properly’ – is being applied and disaster
ensues.
Japan has followed the Keynesian rule-book fairly
faithfully without ever shaking off its post-bubble problems. To the contrary,
the country’s imbalances get scarier by the day, requiring some brutal
catharsis in the not too distant future. Ironically, Richard Koo is an alleged
authority on Japan, yet he prescribes the same or similar policies to the US
today.
Only a return to free and uninhibited markets, real
prices and interest rates, and a return to hard money, can get us out of this
mess.
In the meantime, the debasement of paper money
continues.
No comments:
Post a Comment