There’s a very interesting
article in The Atlantic this week, called “How
Partisans Fool Themselves Into Believing Their Own Spin.” While the author,
Alesh Houdek, engages in some spin of his own, he makes some very good points
that we should keep in mind not only as we look at the potential effects of a
tax increase but as we tackle new ideas and accompanying “facts” in general.
And he has pointed us to a very interesting study, or at least it’s interesting
for those of us who are fascinated by behavioral psychology and behavioral
economics:
We weigh facts and lines of reasoning far more strongly when they favor our
own side, and we minimize the importance and validity of the opposition's
arguments. That may be appropriate behavior in a formal debate, or when we're
trying to sway the opinion of a third party. But to the extent that we internalize
these tendencies, they injure our ability to think and see clearly. And if we
bring them into the sort of open and honest one-on-one political debates that
we'd like to think Americans have with each other, we strain our own
credibility and undermine the possibility of reaching an understanding.
A defense attorney presents the best case for his client's innocence in
court, but he's realistic with himself about what he believes the truth of the
matter is. Too often in political arguments we have drunk our own Kool-Aid.”
A recent
report on three psychological studies by professors from the
University of California, Irvine confirms this bias, and points out that it's
pervasive across a wide range of human situations. Where our moral judgements
come into conflict with evidence, we look for ways to dismiss and minimize the
evidence:
Quoting from the report:
“While individuals can and do appeal to principle in some cases to support
their moral positions, we argue that this is a difficult stance psychologically
because it conflicts with well-rehearsed economic intuitions urging that the
most rational course of action is the one that produces the most favorable
cost-benefit ratio. Our research suggests that people resolve such dilemmas by
bringing cost-benefit beliefs into line with moral evaluations, such that the
right course of action morally becomes the right course of action practically
as well. Study 3 provides experimental confirmation of a pattern implied by
both our own and others' correlational research (e.g., Kahan, 2010):
People shape their descriptive understanding of the world to fit their prescriptive understanding of it. Our findings contribute to a growing body of research demonstrating that moral evaluations affect non-moral judgments such as assessments of cause (Alicke, 2000; Cushman & Youn g, 2011) intention (Knobe, 2003, 2010), and control (Young & Phillips, 2011). At the broadest level, all these examples represent a tendency, long noted by philosophers, for people to have trouble maintaining clear conceptual boundaries between what is and what ought to be (Davis, 1978; Hume, 1740/1985).”
People shape their descriptive understanding of the world to fit their prescriptive understanding of it. Our findings contribute to a growing body of research demonstrating that moral evaluations affect non-moral judgments such as assessments of cause (Alicke, 2000; Cushman & Youn g, 2011) intention (Knobe, 2003, 2010), and control (Young & Phillips, 2011). At the broadest level, all these examples represent a tendency, long noted by philosophers, for people to have trouble maintaining clear conceptual boundaries between what is and what ought to be (Davis, 1978; Hume, 1740/1985).”
This next paragraph is
critical. Read it twice.
The studies further show that this effect is stronger in well-informed,
politically engaged individuals. The more information we have, the higher our
propensity to cheat with it. I've been talking to a lot of people on both sides
of the election, and the thing I'm often struck by is an inability to find any
validity in the opposing side's arguments. By blocking our ability to have
meaningful conversations, this effect is actually harming political discourse.
Given that my readers are just
about the most well-informed and politically engaged group of people anywhere,
we have to make a special effort to think through controversial topics. I make
the effort to constantly question my assumptions and to read people I don’t
agree with. That is why Outside the Box (which highlights the writing of other
analysts and thought leaders and is now published in Friday afternoon) features
such a wide variety of thinking. And few things are more controversial than the
coming tax increase. So let’s walk through a few ideas now and come to some
conclusions independent of our biases.
It would be hard to find
someone who does not agree with the proposition that we need more jobs. The
dismal unemployment rate is at the forefront of any debate on the future of the
economy, and everyone has a plan to stimulate job growth. And while government
jobs are “real” jobs, they require taxes from the private sector or borrowing
from future growth in order to pay salaries. By definition, then, when we say
we want more jobs what we really mean (or should mean) is that we want more
private-sector jobs.
Private-sector jobs do not
appear by magic; they require someone to produce a good or service that other
people will pay for. Typically, that requires putting in place some form of
equipment and/or capital goods so that people can produce the new good or
service. To do what I do, I need a computer, an internet connection, web
servers, editors, production staff, and a coffee maker. While I typically sit
alone and write, it takes a horde of people to produce all the goods and
services that make it possible for me to run my business. Where would I be
without American Airlines? Telephones? Email? I expect 1,000 things to work
seamlessly so that I can sit and write my letter and eventually hit the send
button and expect it to pop into your inbox.
The same is true for millions
of businesses worldwide, both small and large. And while I hope that my own
small part of the economy will grow faster than US GDP, the mathematical
reality is that we’re all in this together. Individual businesses will fail or
succeed on their own, but overall growth is by definition a joint venture. An
economy that is growing is an economy that is producing more jobs. To produce
more jobs requires an investment of time and materials on the part of
individuals and/or businesses. That takes money. Whether it comes from your own
savings or those of family or friends, or from a bank or your friendly vulture
capitalist (that would be me, when I get the chance), starting and maintaining
a business requires capital. In a very real sense, capital is the engine of
growth. And whatever manifestation it may take, capital is essentially savings
in one form or another.
Let’s do a very quick review.
Long-time readers know that there are two, and only two, ways to increase gross
domestic product and grow an economy. You can increase your population or you
can increase productivity. That’s it. That’s the recipe for the secret sauce
that all politicians seek.
Jeremy Grantham (one of my
favorite analysts) wrote in his recent client letter:
The demographic inputs peaked around 1970 at nearly 2% a year growth (there
are many ways to do these calculations, each yielding slightly different
results). They fell to about 1% average growth for the last 30 years and
demographic effects are now down to about 0.2% a year increase in man-hours
where they are likely to remain until 2050, with possibly a very slight
downward bias. Unusually for things economic, these estimates are much more
likely than the typical estimates to be quite accurate, for much is derived
from the existing population profile and social trends, which, like birth
rates, change very slowly. The only variable that is quite likely to jump
around unpredictably is the U.S. immigration policy.
Sidebar: This is why I have
written that at some point in the future even politicians will realize that the
most valuable import we can find is young, educated immigrants. Second would be
young immigrants willing to work. The current immigration policy of the US,
continued under multiple administrations, is puzzling and pointedly
anti-growth. We need to give anyone who gets a degree from a US university a
green card with his diploma. And our embassies should be making it easy for the
best and brightest to find a way here. And a dozen other things need to be
done. But that is another letter.
Grantham noted that a large
part of our productivity growth has come from the increased participation of
women in the labor force, an increase that begin to decline in 2000, not
coincidentally, he says, with the decrease in average annual GDP growth. Here
is a chart of the labor participation rate of women, from the FRED database:
Couple that demographic
reality with a declining number of hours worked (which feeds into
productivity), and you begin to partially account for and understand why the
growth of GDP has been less than 2% for the last 12 years, a far cry from the
3.25% it had been for the previous few hundred years. Throw in a deleveraging
economy, and you have even more headwinds to growth. Leverage on the way up
helps add to the capital base, but decreasing leverage slows growth. Grantham
does his work to suggest that the growth of US GDP will be less than 1% over
the next 18 years. I am not so pessimistic, but neither do I think we will
attain 3% growth for quite some time to come. Given the current realities, I
would be happy with 2%.
Now, let’s talk about capital
formation and tax increases. It seems that a number of people agree that taxes
should be raised on millionaires. I’ve been on several panels and in numerous
conversations where participants adamantly maintained that raising taxes on the
“rich” would have no impact on the economy. I want to do a thought experiment
with you and let you decide if there will be an impact.
Please note that this is not
an argument for or against raising taxes. It may very well be in the common
interest to raise taxes from where they are today. Remember the report on
psychological bias we looked at briefly at the beginning of this letter. If you
start with the assumption that raising taxes is either bad or good and then
look for facts to support your belief, you will not help come to an unbiased
conclusion.
Let’s start with your typical
millionaire individual. For the ease of our math, let’s round off the numbers.
The top federal tax rate is 35%, plus Medicare and property taxes, sales taxes,
state and local income taxes, school taxes, etc. Depending on whether the
individual owns a business, he or she may pay both sides of the Medicare tax.
Let’s assume our millionaire pays 40% “all in” on his $1 million income. That
leaves him with $600,000. Note that in some states and cities this could be
much closer to $500,000. And some people will pay less. The numbers will change
somewhat, but the logic will remain intact.
Let’s assume that our intrepid
millionaire spends $300,000 maintaining his lifestyle, leaving him with another
$300,000 to save and invest. (I’m also assuming he doesn’t have seven kids in
private school, but that’s another story.)
Now, let’s raise his taxes by
5%, which is somewhat less than the likely increase in income taxes and
Medicare taxes currently being discussed. Clinging gamely to his lifestyle, our
millionaire now has $250,000 to save and invest. This still sounds like a lot
to most people, and it is. But the economy now has $50,000 less in gross
national savings.
Whether his taxes are 45%
going to 50% or 55% going to 60% (think NYC), our millionaire will accumulate
less capital over time. And that has to make a difference. How can it not?
Whether or not our individual
millionaires decide to put her savings into bonds or to plow them back into her
personal small businesses or any of a hundred other things she could choose to
do with this money is immaterial. In the aggregate, when you add all the
millionaires together, there is now less money available for capital formation.
To think that their actions will be exactly the same as they would have been
with 20% more money is ludicrous. They may still put money back into their
businesses or invest in other businesses, but the simple fact is that they have
less money to do whatever it is they want to do.
If they cut back on spending
in order to maintain their savings and investment portfolios, then the
merchants who sold them goods and services will have less. Yes, that money will
be spent by the government on other goods and services, and to that extent it
will show up in GDP. But to argue that there will be no impact on savings and
investment and thus capital formation simply makes no sense.
As I’ve repeatedly written,
the preponderance of academic literature suggests that there is a hit to the
growth of GDP from raising taxes. That is different from saying that the raison
d'ĂȘtre for all taxes should be their effect on GDP growth. Certain taxes (and
spending) may very well be worth the resultant lower growth in capital
formation and thus GDP. Healthcare comes to mind.
Given the high correlation
between the growth of the stock market and the growth of GDP, as investors it
behooves us to pay attention to things that affect GDP. At the very least, our
long-term expectations for GDP growth should affect our investment decisions.
But without knowing the exact amount or nature of the tax increases to come,
whether they will be from actually raising rates or from eliminating
deductions, it is hard to say what the effect on the economy will be. Not all
taxes have the same multiplier. Income taxes seem to have a higher multiplier
than consumption taxes, as an example.
That being said, increasing
taxes will drag down GDP growth in both the short and long term. The
longer-term effect will be a decrease in available capital. That $50,000 that
our millionaire does not have this year? Over ten years it becomes $500,000,
and even more if the money is well-used. But if those funds cannot be invested
in productivity-enhancing tools, services, and businesses, there will be fewer
jobs and reduced consumption down the line. There are consequences. As a
country, we must decide whether to pay that price.
But for sure, an increase in
taxes will lower the savings rate. If it does not, then it will lower
consumption. Either is bad for the economy. But let’s focus on capital
formation.
I want to quote one last
section from Grantham’s letter. It is part of his work explaining why he
expects less growth over the coming decades than we have seen in the past. He
notes the reduced capital spending and capital formation in the developed
world. Let me hasten to add that he does not say anything
about tax increases, nor does he draw the conclusions I have. What he does
speak to is the importance of capital formation and productivity:
Typically I see less significance than others in debt and monetary factors
and more in real factors. When someone says that China is building its trains
and houses on debt I think, “No, they are built by real people with real
bricks, cement, and steel and whatever happens to the debt, these assets will
still be there.” (They may fall down but that’s a separate story; you can build
a bad high rise with or without debt). So I take the quality and quantity of
capital and people very seriously: they are the keys to growth and a healthy
economy. A badly trained, badly educated workforce is a problem we will get to,
but reduced, abnormally low capital investment, particularly in the U.S., is
the current topic. My friend and economic consultant Andrew Smithers in London
has a theory deserving much more attention in my opinion, and that is his
concept of the “Bonus Culture.” When I was a young analyst, companies like
International Paper and International Harvester would drive us all crazy, for
just as the supply/demand situation was getting tight and fat profits seemed
around the corner, they and their competitors would all build new plants and
everyone would drown in excess capacity. The CEOs were all obsessed with market
share and would throw capital spending at everything. It might not have been
the way to maximize an individual company’s profit but it was great for jobs
and growth. Now, in the bonus culture, new capacity is regarded with great
suspicion. It tends to lower profitability in the near term and, occasionally
these days, exposes the investing company to a raider. It is far safer to hold
tight to the money and, when the stock needs a little push, buy some of your
own stock back. This is going on today as I write, and on a big scale
(approximately $500 billion this year). Do this enough, though, and we will
begin to see disappointing top-line revenues and a slower growing general
economy, such as we may be seeing right now.
My colleagues have put together Exhibit 5, which shows the long-term
history of capital spending for the U.S. (The savings and investment rate has a
25% correlation with long-run GDP growth.) Mostly the data in Exhibit 5
reflects a lower capital spending rate responding to slower growth. The circled
area, though, suggests an abnormally depressed level of capital spending, which
seems highly likely to be a depressant on future growth: obviously you embed
new technologies and new potential productivity more slowly if you have less
new equipment. This currently reduced investment level appears to be about 4%
below anything that can be explained by the decline in the growth trend. If
this decline is proactive, if you will, and not a reflection of earlier
declines in the growth rate, then based on longer term correlations it is
likely to depress future growth by, conservatively, 0.2% a year.
All the participants in last
week’s Post Election Economic Summit were either calling outright for a
recession next year or were not optimistic. Count me in the latter camp. It is
clear that taxes on every worker will go up, because the “tax holiday” of 2% of
the total Social Security payment is going to be removed. That is $1,000 per
year for someone making $50,000. This tax cut was put in place because everyone
agreed it would stimulate the economy. While no one is talking about it, the
effects are just as great in the downward direction when the tax comes back.
They just are. The total is about 0.75% of GDP. Given your academic view on tax
multipliers, that the total effect can be anywhere from 0.75% to more than 2%
of GDP.
Anyone arguing that tax
increase has no effect now should have said publicly that cutting that tax
would have no effect two years ago. Just saying.
Add in whatever other tax
increases or spending cuts will accompany the Social Security tax increase (you
can call it what you want), and an economy that is barely growing at 2% could
be in for a very slow period. Not the stuff that job growth is made of.
Further, businesses will have increased costs under Obamacare. Some costs kick
in quicker than others.
ANY further hit from Europe or
Japan could call into question global growth. We are an interconnected world,
and what happens in those nations will affect us. While I might feel
differently if I were a German or Dutch or Finnish voter, those of us in the US
should stand up and applaud whenever the eurozone postpones a crisis. At our
Summit, Mohamed El-Erian was very clearly worried about the crisis in Europe.
(He was on fire. We will post his entire portion of the Summit later this week.
I will let you know. You do want to watch it.)
Any hit to Europe will likely
push the US into recession. It is an uncomfortable place to be when you need
Europe not to have a crisis in order for your own economy to keep growing. I
keep wondering how long Europe can keep kicking that can.
All of which feeds into a
theme that Barry Ritholtz brought up. He was more concerned about what he
called an “earnings cliff” than a fiscal cliff. And earnings are part and
parcel of GDP. We know what happens to earnings in a recession. And to
employment and to budget deficits. We have only to look at Europe to see what
happens when too much austerity is applied too fast. Slow and steady should be
the rule. I am deadly serious about going on a fiscal diet; I just don’t want
to try and lose it all at once.
No comments:
Post a Comment