Although the movement
to “End the Fed” has a considerable popular following, only a very tiny number
of economists—our illustrious contributors amongst them—take the possibility
seriously. For the rest, the Federal Reserve System is, not an ideal currency
system to be sure (for who would dare to call it that?), but, implicitly at
least, the best of all possible systems. And while there’s no shortage of
proposals for reforming it almost all of them call only for mere tinkering.
Tough though their love may be, the fact remains that most economists are stuck
on the Fed.
This veneration of the Fed has long struck me as
perverse. Its record can hardly be said, after all, to supply grounds for
complacency, much less for the belief that no other system could possibly do
better. (Indeed that record, as Bill Lastrapes,
Larry White and I have shown,
even makes it difficult to claim that the Fed has improved upon the evidently
flawed National Currency system it replaced.) Further, as the Fed is both a
monopoly and a central planning agency, one would expect economists’ general
opposition to monopolies and to central planning, as informed by their welfare theorems and
by the general collapse of socialism, to prejudice them against it. Yet instead
of ganging up to look into market-based alternatives to the Fed, the profession
for the most part has relegated such inquiries to its fringe.
Why? The question warrants an answer from those of us
who insist that exploring alternatives to the Fed is worthwhile, if only to
counter people’s natural but nevertheless mistaken inclination to assume that
the rest of the profession isn’t interested in such alternatives because it has
already carefully considered—and rejected—them.
It’s tempting to blame Fedophilia, or what Larry White calls
“status quo” bias in monetary research,
on the Fed’s direct influence upon the economics profession. According to
White, in 2005 the Fed employed about 27 percent more full-time macro- and
monetary (including banking) economists than the top 50 US academic economics
departments combined, while disseminating much of their research gratis through
various in-house publications or as working papers. Perhaps not surprisingly,
despite a thorough review of such publications White could not find “a single
Fed-published article that calls for eliminating, privatizing, or even
restructuring the Fed.” That professional monetary economics journals are not
much better may in turn reflect the fact, also documented by White, that
Fed-affiliated economists also dominate those journals' editorial boards.
But I doubt that a reluctance to bite the hand that
feeds them is the only, or even the most important, reason why most economists
seldom question the Fed’s desirability. Another reason, I suppose, is their
desire to distance themselves from…kooks. Let’s face it: more than a few
persons who’d like to “End the Fed” want to do so because they think the
Rothschilds run it, that it had JFK killed because he planned to revive the
silver dollar, and that the basic plan for it was hatched not by the
Congressional Committee in charge of monetary reform but by a cabal of Wall
Street bankers at a top-secret meeting on Jekyll Island.
Oh, wait: the last claim is actually true. But claims
like the others give reasonable and well-informed Fed critics a bad name, while
giving others reason for wishing to put as much distance as they can between
themselves and the anti-Fed fringe. (And please don’t bother to write telling
me that the Fed really is a Zionist conspiracy or whatever, or I will
personally arrange to have you tracked down and assassinated by someone named
Rothschild, even if I have to have some hit man’s name legally changed for the
purpose.)
I’m convinced that imagination, or the lack of it,
also plays a part. To some extent the problem is too much rather than too
little imagination. With fiat money, and a discretionary central bank, it’s
always theoretically possible to have the money stock (or some other nominal
variable) behave just like it ought to, according to whichever macroeconomic
theory or model one prefers. In other words, a modern central bank is always
technically capable of doing the right thing, just as a chimpanzee jumping on a
keyboard is technically capable of typing-out War and Peace. Just as
obviously, any conceivable alternative to a discretionary central bank, whether
based on competition and a commodity standard or frozen fiat base or on some
other “automatic” mechanisms, is bound to be imperfect, judged relative to
some—indeed any—theoretical ideal. Consequently, an economist need only imagine
that a central bank might somehow be managed according to his or her own
particular monetary policy ideals to reckon it worthwhile to try and nudge it
in that direction, but not to consider other conceivable arrangements.
That there’s a fallacy of composition of sorts at play
here should be obvious, for a dozen economists might hold as many completely
different monetary policy ideals; yet every one might be a Fedophile simply
because the Fed could cater to his or her beliefs. In actual fact, of course,
the Fed’s conduct can at most satisfy only one of them, and is indeed likely to
satisfy none at all, and so might actually prove distinctly inferior to what
some non-central bank alternative would achieve. So in letting their
imaginations get the best of them, all twelve economists end up endorsing
what’s really the inferior option. And if you don’t think economists are really
capable of such naievete, I refer you to the literature on currency boards, in
which one routinely encounters arguments to the effect that central banks are
always better than currency boards because they might be better. Or how about those critics
of the gold standard who, having first observed how, under such a standard,
gold discoveries will cause inflation, go on to conclude, triumphantly, that a
fiat-money issuing central-bank is better because it might keep prices stable?
But if economists let their imaginations run wild in
having their ideal central banks stand in for the real McCoys, those same imaginations
tend to run dry when it comes to contemplating radical alternatives to the
monetary status quo. Regarding
conventional beliefs concerning the need for government-run coin factories,
which he (rightly) dismissed as so much poppycock, Herbert Spencer observed,
“So much more does a realized fact influence us than an imagined one, that had
the baking of bread been hitherto carried on by government agents, probably the
supply of bread by private enterprise would scarcely be conceived possible, much
less advantageous.” Economists who haven’t put any effort into imagining how
non-central bank based monetary systems might work find it all too easy to
simply suppose that they can’t work, or at least that they can’t work at all
well. The workings of decentralized markets are often subtle; while such
markets' ability to solve many difficult coordination problems is, not only
mysterious to untrained observers, but often difficult if not impossible even
for experts to fathom except by means of painstaking investigations. In
comparison monetary central planning is duck soup—on paper, anyway.
Nor does the way monetary economics is taught help. In
other subjects the welfare theorems are taken seriously. In classes on
international trade, for example, time is always spent, early on, on the
implications of free trade: never mind that the world has never witnessed
perfectly free trade, and probably never will; it’s understood that the
consequences of tariffs and other sorts of state interference can only be
properly assessed by comparing them to the free trade alternative, and no one
who hasn’t studied that alternative can expect to have his or her
pronouncements about the virtues of protectionism taken seriously. In classes
in monetary economics, on the other hand, the presence of a central bank—a
monetary central planner, that is—is assumed from the get-go, and no serious
attention is given to the implications of “free trade in money and
banking." Consequently, when most monetary economists talk about the virtues
of this or that central bank, they’re mostly talking through their hats,
because they haven’t a clue concerning what other institutions might be
present, and what they might be up to, if the central bank wasn’t there.
Since monetary systems not managed by central banks,
including some very successful ones, have in fact existed, economists’
inability to envision such systems is also evidence of their ignorance of
economic history. That ignorance in turn, among younger economists at least, is
a predictable consequence of the now-orthodox view that history can be safely
boiled down to a bunch of correlation coefficients, so that they need only
gather enough numbers and run enough regressions to discover everything worth
knowing about the past.
Those who’ve been spared such “training,” on the other
hand, often have a purblind view of the history of money and banks—one that
brings to mind Saul Steinberg’s
famous New Yorker cover depicting a 9th-Avenuer’s view of the
world, with its almost uninhabited desert between the Hudson and the Pacific,
and China, Japan, and Russia barely visible on the horizon. If he or she knows
any monetary history at all, the typical (which is to say American) economist
knows something about that history in the U.S., and perhaps considerably less
about events in Great Britain. Theirs is, in short, just the right amount of
knowledge to be very dangerous indeed.
And dangerous it has been. In particular, because the
U.S. before 1914, and England before the Bank of England began acting as a
lender of last resort, happened to suffer frequent financial crises,
economists' historical nearsightedness has given rise to the conventional
wisdom that any fractional-reserve banking system lacking a lender of last
resort must be crisis-prone, and to clever (if utterly fantastic) formal models serving to illustrate the same view (or, according to
economists’ twisted rhetoric, to “prove” it “rigorously”). It has,
correspondingly, led economists to ignore or at least to underestimate the
extent to which legal restrictions, including unit banking laws in the U.S. and
the six-partner rule in England, contributed to the deficiencies of those
countries’ banking systems. Finally, and most regrettably, it has caused
economists to overlook altogether the possibility that the monopolization of
paper currency has itself been more a cause of than a cure for financial
instability.
The good news is that Fedophilia is curable. Milton
Friedman, for one, was a recovering Fedophile: later in his career he repudiated the mostly-conventional arguments
he’d once put forward in defense of a currency monopoly. Friedman, of course,
was a special case: a famous proponent of free markets, he had more reason than
most economists do to view claims of market failure with skepticism, even if
he’d once subscribed to them himself. Even so his was only a half-hearted change
of heart, in part (I believe) because he still
hadn't drawn the lessons he might have from the banking experiences of
countries other than the U.S. and England.
Friedman’s case suggests that it will take some pretty
intense therapy to deprogram other Fed inamoratos, including a
regimen of required readings. Charles Conant’sHistory of Modern Banks of
Issue will help them to overcome their historical parochialism. Vera Smith’s The Rationale of Central
Banking will do more of the same, while also
exposing them to the lively debates that took place between advocates and
opponents of currency monopolies before the former (supported by their
governments’ ravenous Treasuries) swept the field. The Experience of Free Banking, edited by Kevin Dowd (with contributions by several Freebanking.org contributors including yours truly)
gathers studies of a number of past, decentralized currency systems, showing
how they tended to be more stable than their more more centralized
counterparts, while another collection, Rondo Cameron’s Banking in the Early Stages of
Industrialization, shows that less
centralized systems were also better at fostering economic development.
Finally, instead of being allowed to merely pay lip service to Walter Bagehot’s Lombard Street, Fedophile’s should be forced, first to read it from cover to cover,
and then to re-read out-loud those passages (there are several) in which
Bagehot explains that there’d be no need for lenders of last resort had unwise
legislation not created centralized (“one reserve”) currency systems in the
first place. The last step works especially well in group therapy.
Of course even the most vigorous deprogramming regimen
is unlikely to alter the habits of hard-core Fed enthusiasts. But it might at
the very least make them more inclined to engage in serious debate with the
Fed’s critics, instead of allowing the Fed's apologists to go on believing that
they answer those critics convincingly simply by rolling their eyes.
No comments:
Post a Comment