By MATTHEW KAMINSKI
As an economic crisis manager, Leszek Balcerowicz has
few peers. When communism fell in Europe, he pioneered "shock
therapy" to slay hyperinflation and build a free market. In the late
1990s, he jammed a debt ceiling into his country's constitution, handcuffing
future free spenders. When he was central-bank governor from 2001 to 2007, his
hard-money policies avoided a credit boom and likely bust.
Poland was the only country in the European Union to
avoid recession in 2009 and has been the fastest-growing EU economy since. Mr.
Balcerowicz dwells little on this achievement. He sounds too busy in
"battle"—his word—against bad policy.
"Most problems are the result of bad
politics," he says. "In a democracy, you have lots of pressure groups
to expand the state for reasons of money, ideology, etc. Even if they are
angels in the government, which is not the case, if there is not a
counterbalance in the form of proponents of limited government, then there will
be a shift toward more statism and ultimately into stagnation and crisis."
Looking around the world, there is no shortage of
questionable policies. A series of bailouts for Greece and others has saved the
euro, but who knows for how long. EU leaders closed their summit in Brussels on
Friday by deferring hard decisions on entrenching fiscal discipline and pro-growth
policies. Across the Atlantic, Washington looks no closer to a "fiscal
cliff" deal. And the Federal Reserve on Wednesday made a fourth foray into
"quantitative easing" to keep real interest rates low by buying bonds
and printing money.
As a former central banker, Mr. Balcerowicz struggles
to find the appropriate word for Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke's latest invention: "Unprecedented,"
"a complete anathema," "more uncharted waters." He says
such "unconventional" measures trap economies in an unvirtuous cycle.
Bankers expect lower interest rates to spur growth. When that fails, as in
Japan, they have no choice but to stick with easing.
"While the benefits of non-conventional
[monetary] policies are short lived, the costs grow with time," he says.
"The longer you practice these sorts of policies, the more difficult it is
to exit it. Japan is trapped." Anemic Japan is the prime example, but now
the U.S., Britain and potentially the European Central Bank are on the same
road.
If he were in Mr. Bernanke's shoes, Mr. Balcerowicz
says he'd rethink the link between easy money and economic growth. Over time,
he says, lower interest rates and money printing presses harm the
economy—though not necessarily or primarily through higher inflation.
First, Bernanke-style policies "weaken incentives
for politicians to pursue structural reforms, including fiscal reforms,"
he says. "They can maintain large deficits at low current rates." It
indulges the preference of many Western politicians for stimulus spending. It
means they don't have to grapple as seriously with difficult choices, say, on
Medicare.
Another unappreciated consequence of easy money,
according to Mr. Balcerowicz, is the easing of pressure on the private economy
to restructure. With low interest rates, large companies "can just
refinance their loans," he says. Banks are happy to go along. Adjustments
are delayed, markets distorted.
By his reading, the increasingly politicized Fed has
in turn warped America's political discourse. The Lehman collapse did help
clean up the financial sector, but not the government. Mr. Balcerowicz marvels
that federal spending is still much higher than before the crisis, which isn't
the case in Europe. "The greatest neglect in the U.S. is fiscal," he
says. The dollar lets the U.S. "get a lot of cheap financing to finance
bad policies," which is "dangerous to the world and perhaps dangerous
to the U.S."
The Fed model is spreading. Earlier this fall, the
European Central Bank announced an equally unprecedented plan to buy the bonds
of distressed euro-zone countries. The bank, in essence, said it was willing to
print any amount of euros to save the single currency.
Mr. Balcerowicz sides with the head of Germany's
Bundesbank, the sole dissenter on the ECB board to the bond-buying scheme. He
says it violates EU treaties. "And second, when the Fed is printing money,
it is not buying bonds of distressed states like California—it's more general,
it's spreading it," he says. "The ECB is engaging in regional policy.
I don't think you can justify this."
"So they know better," says Mr. Balcerowicz,
about the latest fads in central banking. "Risk premiums are too high—according
to them! They are above the judgments of the markets. I remember this
from socialism: 'We know better!'"
Mr. Balcerowicz, who is 65, was raised in a
state-planned Poland. He got a doctorate in economics, worked briefly at the
Communist Party's Institute of Marxism-Leninism, and advised the Solidarity
trade union before the imposition of martial law in 1981. He came to prominence
in 1989 as the father of the "Balcerowicz Plan." Overnight, prices
were freed, subsidies were slashed and the zloty currency was made convertible.
It was harsh medicine, but the Polish economy recovered faster than more
gradual reformers in the old Soviet bloc.
Shock or no, Mr. Balcerowicz remains adamant that
fixes are best implemented as quickly as possible. Europe's PIGS—Portugal,
Italy, Greece, Spain—moved slowly. By contrast, Mr. Balcerowicz offers the
BELLs: Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania.
These EU countries went through a credit boom-bust
after 2009. Their economies tanked, Latvia's alone by nearly 20% that year.
Denied EU bailouts, these governments were forced to adopt harsher measures
than Greece. Public spending was slashed, including for government salaries.
The adjustment hurt but recovery came by 2010. The BELL GDP growth curves are
V-shaped. The PIGS decline was less steep, but prolonged and worse over time.
The systemic
changes in the BELLs took a while to work, yet Mr. Balcerowicz says the radical
approach has another, short-run benefit. He calls it the "confidence
effect." When markets saw governments implement the reforms, their
borrowing costs dropped fast, while the yields for the PIGS kept rising.
Greece focused on raising taxes, putting off
expenditure cuts. They got it backward, says Mr. Balcerowicz. "If you
reduce through reform current spending, which is too excessive, you are far
more likely to be successful with fiscal consolidation than if you increase
taxes, which are already too high."
He adds: "Somehow the impression for many people
is that increasing taxes is correct and reducing spending is incorrect. It is
ideologically loaded." This applies in Greece, most of Europe and the
current debate in the U.S.
During his various stints in government in Poland, the
name Balcerowicz was often a curse word. In the 1990s, he was twice deputy
prime minister and led the Freedom Union party. As a pol, his cool and abrasive
style won him little love and cost him votes, even as his policies worked. At the
central bank, he took lots of political heat for his tight monetary policy and
wasn't asked to stay on after his term ended in 2007.
Mr. Balcerowicz admits he was an easy scapegoat.
"People tend to personalize reforms. I don't mind. I take responsibility
for the reforms I launched." He says he "understands politicians when
they give in [on reform], but I do not accept it." It's up to the
proponents of the free market to fight for their ideas and make politicians
aware of the electoral cost of not reforming.
On bailouts, Mr. Balcerowicz strikes an agnostic note.
They can mitigate a crisis—as long as they don't reduce the pressure to reform.
The BELL vs. PIGS comparison suggests the bailouts have slowed reform, but he
notes recent movement in southern Europe to deregulate labor markets, privatize
and cut spending—in other words, serious steps to spur growth.
"Once the euro has been created," Mr.
Balcerowicz says, "it's worth keeping it." The single currency is no
different than the gold standard, "which worked pretty well," he
says. In both cases, member countries have to keep their budget deficits in
check and labor markets flexible to stay competitive. Which makes him
cautiously optimistic on the euro.
"It's important to remember that six, eight, 10
years ago Germany was like Italy, and it reformed," he says. Before Berlin
pushed through an overhaul of the welfare state, Germany was called the
"sick man of Europe." "There are no European solutions for the
Italians' problem. But there are Italian solutions. Not bailouts, but better
policies."
Why do some countries change for the better in a
crisis and others don't? Mr. Balcerowicz puts the "popular interpretation
of the root causes" of the crisis high on the list.
"There is a lot of intellectual confusion,"
he says. "For example, the financial crisis has happened in the financial
sector. Therefore the reason for the crisis must be something in the financial
sector. Sounds logical, but it's not. It's like saying the reason you sneeze
through your nose is your nose."
The markets didn't "fail" but were distorted
by bad policies. He mentions "too big to fail," the Fed's easy money, Fannie Mae and the housing boom. Those are the hard explanations.
"Many people like cheap moralizing," he says. "What a pleasant
feeling to condemn greed. It's popular."
"Generally in the West, intellectuals like to
blame the markets," he says. "There is a widespread belief that
crises occur in capitalism mostly. The word crisis is associated with the word
capitalism. While if you look in a comparative way, you see that the largest
economic and also human catastrophes happen in non-market systems, when there's
a heavy concentration of political power—Stalin, Mao, the Khmer Rouge, many
other cases."
Going back to the 19th century, industrializing
economies recovered best after a crisis with no or limited intervention. Yet
Keynesians continue to insist that only the state can compensate for the flaws
of the market, he says.
"This idea that markets tend to fall into
self-perpetuating crises and only wise government can extract the country out
of this crisis implicitly assumes that you have two kinds of people. Normal
people who are operating in the markets, and better people who work for the
state. They deny human nature."
Gathering the
essays for his new collection, "Discovering Freedom," Mr. Balcerowicz
realized that "you don't need to read modern economists" to
understand what's happening today. Hume, Smith, Hayek and Tocqueville are all
there. He loves Madison's "angels" quote: "If men were angels,
no government would be necessary. If angels were to govern men, neither
external nor internal controls on government would be necessary."
No comments:
Post a Comment