The Egyptian republic's economic course has been
problematic, to say the least. Gamal Abdul Nasser's experiment with nationalization, central planning and
Soviet-assisted industrialization left the economy hobbled by regulation and
inefficiency. Anwar Sadat's successor regime relaxed the government's grip, but accumulated a
mountain of foreign debt that caused stagnation through much of the 1980s.
But fortune favored the economy thereafter. Much of
Egypt's external debt was forgiven or restructured in the wake of the Gulf War.
And in the decade that followed, per capita GDP calculated in terms of
purchasing power rose by one-third simply on the strength of containing both
inflation and budget deficits.
Mubarak subsequently introduced major market-based
reforms -- steps toward privatization and deregulation -- that permitted growth
to accelerate to the 7 percent range. His technocrats also negotiated the
global recession without a tumble, responding with a domestic stimulus (mostly
infrastructure investment) that largely offset declines in private investment
and exports. In the two years prior to the Arab Spring, the economy seemed to
be back on the rapid development track.
However, in the years of high growth, though
unemployment in the formal market rarely fell below 9
percent, youth
unemployment hovered around
25 percent, and increasing
numbers of college graduates never managed to get a first job. Moreover, the
stimulus barely touched smaller enterprises, reinforcing the popular impression
that the game was rigged in favor of insiders.
The revolution and lingering uncertainty during the
transition exacted a huge toll on economic performance. The economy has since
been creeping back, but at a pace hopelessly short of the 7 percent pace needed
to absorb new entrants to the labor force. And the prospects for acceleration are
mixed.
The first economic challenge to the newly elected
government is to reduce uncertainty about the viability of Egypt's finances.
Before the revolution, the Ministry of Finance had targeted a gradual reduction
in the overall fiscal deficit from 8.1 percent of GDP in 2009-10 to 3.5 percent
of GDP by 2015 -- and thereby to decrease the public debt from 77 percent of
GDP to 60 percent.
Government debt per se creates no immediate threat
since relatively little of it is owed in currencies other than Egyptian pounds.
But deficit reduction will almost certainly be a condition for much-needed
support from
the IMF. In any event,
permitting the recent surge in deficit spending to continue for much longer
would undermine the prospects for a return to rapid growth.
That's because government borrowing is absorbing much
of Egypt's relatively meager domestic savings, crowding out private investment.
Credit has been increasingly skewed towards support of the government and away
from financing private activity.
The other side of the budget ledger matters, too, of
course. As the economy recovers, there will be scope for raising revenue by
widening the tax base, as well as by fighting corruption and tax evasion. One
high-priority target is the revision of export contracts, particularly for
natural gas, which would bring in billions in added revenues.
Then there's the issue of price and exchange rate
stability. Egypt, like other relatively small open economies, must reconcile
conflicting goals here. It needs an exchange rate that makes the country an
attractive venue for foreign direct investment and a competitive source of
goods and services for global trade. But Egypt is also a big importer of food
and fuel, so both domestic inflation and government spending can be quite
sensitive to depreciation in the exchange rate.
That explains why the Central Bank of Egypt (CBE) has been spending down its foreign
currency reserves in the teeth of declining foreign investment, foreign tourism
income, and Suez Canal receipts. But it also explains why the CBE has been of
two minds on monetary policy.
Responding to the economic downturn, it cut minimum
bank reserves to ease constraints on domestic liquidity in the face of surging
government borrowing. However, the CBE has been reluctant to lower interest rates
for fear of depressing the Egyptian pound's exchange rate, encouraging capital
flight or creating expectations of higher inflation.
The new government will have little choice but to
continue this juggling act. With foreign exchange reserves badly depleted,
Egypt must secure credit from the IMF and other international lenders that
follow in the IMF's wake. A tentative
deal providing
$4.8 billion contingent on budget reforms was announced on November 20, and
another $10 billion in aid from other donors is likely to follow. This will
give the CBE the resources to stabilize the exchange rate, and thereby to
contain import-price inflation, until Egypt regains the confidence of
investors.
While Mubarak's deregulation strategy paid off in
terms of growth, it allowed corruption to fester: Egypt, ranked a wretched 112th among 183
countries on Transparency
International's Corruption
Perception Index in 2011. The most corrosive consequence of corruption -- and
more generally, the failure to provide equal protection of economic rights --
is that it reduces social and
economic mobility. Small- and
medium-sized enterprises, the likely engines of mobility, face daunting
barriers when they compete with the incumbent elite.
The list of impediments to free enterprise in Egypt is
long. According to the World Bank, a business owner needs 218
days to obtain a construction permit. It takes seven procedures and 72 days to register
property. Getting an electricity hookup averages seven procedures and 54 days,
and costs four-and-a-half times the annual income of an average Egyptian.
Moreover, despite substantial growth that made Egypt's industrial base globally
competitive in key areas and raised the economy to what the World Bank calls "lower-middle
income" status over the past two decades, the discrimination against small business
only heightened.
Market reforms are thus a key to fixing what ails
Egypt, increasing the potential rate of growth while opening the door to new
entrepreneurs and creating jobs to absorb the burgeoning workforce. But such
reform is an immensely difficult process in the face of elites that have little
to gain and much to lose from change.
The mainstay of Egypt's efforts to deal with poverty
is the array of food and fuel subsidies noted earlier. One problem with this
approach is that it distorts consumer prices, creating incentives to waste food
and fuel. But the most troubling aspect of the subsidies as now constituted is
that most of the benefit goes to households and businesses that aren't really
needy. Two-thirds of the cost of the subsidy system is linked to fuel. Yet,
according to household surveys, less than 5 percent of the fuel subsidies aid
the bottom-fifth of the income distribution.
Much the same can be said for food subsidies.
Two-thirds of all households now have ration cards, and the bulk of the benefit
is going to the middle class. Dumping the subsidies overnight (and replacing
them with cash grants to the poor) would not be politically practical. I favor gradual
replacement, focusing on
the fuel subsidies, which cost more and matter less to the poor. And this is
apparently the direction approved by the IMF. But it will be critical to link
the phase-out to cash grants and/or in-kind support to the vulnerable.
While transfers must be part of any plan to cope with
poverty, they shouldn't be viewed as a substitute for jobs. Restoration of
Egypt's once-booming tourism industry, which is more labor-intensive than most
modern industries, should thus be a top priority. But the key to job creation
in the long-run is a flowering of small- and medium-sized enterprises that can
make productive use of unskilled labor, as well as aiding mobility for
middle-class entrepreneurs.
To that end, these firms need better access to credit.
While subsidizing credit can be a slippery slope -- the costs are hard to
contain, and the target group has a way of expanding -- some preferred access
makes sense to offset the capital market's bias toward large-scale enterprise.
This might take the form of direct business loans or credit guarantees through
private banks. Moreover, the government cannot afford to give short shrift to
rural areas, where the poverty is greatest and the exit to cities is creating
social dislocation.
Consider, too, in this regard, the importance of
bringing the large numbers of small
businesses that find
it too expensive to operate legally into the open. The astonishing size of this
underground economy -- by one estimate, it accounts for 40 percent of all employment -- reflects the general
difficulty of doing business in a climate of corruption and bureaucratic
indifference. But until underground enterprises become part of the formal
economy, they will not directly benefit from measures designed to make it
easier to challenge entrenched producers.
While unemployment is a chronic problem for Egypt, its
nature has changed considerably in the last few decades. It's no surprise that
unemployment is exceptionally high among the young (around 25 percent) --
high fertility rates in the 1990s guaranteed unmanageable labor force growth
now. What is surprising is that young college graduates are faring no better
than their less-educated peers.
One reason: As the government shed enterprises in the
last decade, it ceased to be a reliable employer of last resort for college
graduates. Another: Business owners traditionally give first priority in employment
to relatives. But arguably
the most important reason is that universities
don't provide the skills that the rapidly evolving Egyptian private sector
needs.
The main issue isn't underinvestment in tertiary
education -- one-third of high school graduates go to university -- but the system's
failure to make good use of the resources. The new government thus faces the
difficult task of remaking a higher-education establishment built for a
different era.
Egypt's recent economic history is punctuated by
ironies. In particular, development proved to be profoundly destabilizing,
dislocating millions of citizens in the rush to cities, raising the visibility
of a detested new class of crony capitalists and creating expectations of
mobility that were impossible to realize.
This problem is hardly unique to Egypt -- think China
and India. But the Mubarak regime lacked the political legitimacy to survive
it. The new government's task is to restore that sense of legitimacy without
sacrificing the growth that has, in many ways, changed Egypt for the better.
And one key to success will be to convince ordinary Egyptians that they have a
real voice in the process. No easy task, indeed.
No comments:
Post a Comment