In 1968, America was literally over the moon. Apollo 7
had just made the first manned lunar orbit and the nation would soon witness
Neil Armstrong’s moonwalk. The United States was winning the war in Southeast
Asia and the Great Society was on the verge of eliminating poverty. I remember
my father taking me to the Buick dealership that summer in Connellsville,
Pennsylvania, where he bought a 1969 Electra. As we drove home I asked him why
we had bought the 1969 model when we had the 1968 one, which seemed equally
good.
“That’s just what you do now,” my father said, “Every
year you go and get a new car.” “Wouldn’t it be better,” I asked as a
precocious nine year-old, “if we saved our money in case a depression
happened?” I will
never forget my father’s reply: “Son, the next depression will be completely different from the one
that I knew as a boy. In that depression, virtually nobody had any money so if
you had even a little, you could buy nearly anything. In the next depression,
everyone will have plenty of money but it won’t buy much of anything.” Little did I realize, then, how
prescient my father would prove to be.
Five years have passed since the beginning
of the Great Recession. Growth is slow, joblessness is elevated,
and the knock-on effects continue to drag down the global economy. The panic in
financial markets in 2008 that caused a systemic crisis and a sharp fall in
asset values still weighs on markets around the world. The primary difference
between today and the 1930s, when the U.S. experienced its last systemic
crisis, has been the response by policymakers. Having the benefit of hindsight,
policymakers acted swiftly to avoid the mistakes of the Great Depression by
applying Keynesian solutions. Today, I believe we are in the midst of the
Keynesian Depression that my father predicted. Like the last depression, we are
likely to live with the unintended consequences of the policy response for
years to come.
This Depression is Brought to You By...
John Maynard Keynes (1883—1946) was a
British economist and the chief architect of contemporary
macroeconomic theory. In the 1930s, he overturned classical economics with his
monumental General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, a book that, among
other things, sought to explain the Great Depression
and made prescriptions on how to escape it and avoid future economic
catastrophes. Lord Keynes, a Cambridge educated statistician by
training, held various cabinet positions in the British government, was the
U.K.’s representative at the 1944 Bretton Woods conference and, along with
Milton Friedman, is recognized as the most influential economic thinker of the
20th century.
Keynes believed that classical economic theory, which
focused on the long-run was a misleading guide for policymakers. He famously
quipped that, “in the long run we’re all dead.” His
view was that aggregate demand, not the classical theory of supply and demand,
determines economic output. He
also believed that governments could positively intervene in markets and use
deficit spending to smooth out business cycles, thereby lessening the pain of
economic contractions. Keynes called this “priming the pump.”
On Your Mark, Get Set, Spend
Since the Second World War, policymakers
concerned with both fiscal and monetary policy have opportunistically followed
certain Keynesian principles, particularly using government spending as a
stabilizer during periods of economic contraction. In 1968,
steady economic growth and low inflation had led optimists to declare that the
business cycle was dead. When President Nixon ended gold convertibility of the
dollar in 1971 he justified it by declaring that he was a Keynesian. Even
Milton Friedman, founder of the monetary school of economics, told Time
magazine that from a methodological standpoint, “We’re all Keynesians now.”
In dampening each successive downturn,
authorities accumulated increasingly larger deficits and brought about a debt
supercycle that lasted in excess of half a century. The
complementary aspect of Keynes’ guidance on deficit spending – raising taxes
during upswings – was rarely followed because of its political unpopularity. As
a result of the constant fiscal support without the tax increases, businesses
and households became comfortable operating with continuously higher leverage
ratios. The conventional wisdom was that this
government backstop could never be exhausted.
The calamity in the financial system in
2007 and 2008 signaled the beginning of the unraveling of the global debt
supercycle. The Keynesian model dictated that the best way to fix the problem was to
run large deficits and increase the money supply. Keynes had based his
prescriptions for this type of action on the early mismanagement of the Great
Depression which he felt had prolonged the losses and hardship during that
time. As is the case with most groundbreaking philosophies, Keynes’
disciples carried his views much further than could have been imagined during the period in which the master
lived.
The Depression My Father Knew
Keynes viewed governments’ attempts at
belt-tightening during the Great Depression as ill-timed. Although
President Roosevelt invested in massive public works projects under the New
Deal starting in 1933, almost four years into the crisis, the U.S. government
maintained a policy of attempting to balance the budget as the depression raged
on. Keynes’s response was: “The boom, not
the slump, is the right time for austerity at the Treasury.” The other problem, according to
Keynes, was that the Federal Reserve’s attempts to lower real interest rates
and inject cash into the system were too modest and too late to avoid what he
referred to as a liquidity trap, leading people to hoard cash instead of
consuming.
To illustrate the dynamics of the liquidity trap
Keynes cleverly invoked the analogy of “pushing on a string.” He said that at
some point, attempting to stimulate demand by
easing credit conditions is like trying to push a string that is tied to an
object you want to move. Whereas
you can easily pull something toward you by the string to which an object is
tied (raising interest rates to slow growth), attempting to carry out the
opposite by reversed means (lowering interest rates to try to induce lending to
otherwise unwilling borrowers) is not always successful. This is especially
true when the rate of inflation becomes so low that it becomes impossible to
set interest rates below it.
This Time It’s Different
What sets the current downturn apart from any other
since the Great Depression is that, for the first time since the 1930s, we
have had severe asset deflation (declining real prices) in the face of relative
price stability. Periods of asset deflation occurred between
the 1960s and 1990s, but nominal prices were supported by rising inflation
levels. Against the backdrop of a rising price level, nominal asset prices
remained stable or continued to increase as real asset prices declined. This
protected asset-based lenders from severe losses resulting from declining
nominal prices.
During the 2008 crisis, inflation levels were close to
zero and unable to offset falling real asset values to stabilize nominal
prices. This caused a debt deflation spiral to take hold as nominal prices
fell. In contrast to the Great Depression,
policymakers took extreme measures in 2008 to prevent a total collapse of the
financial system and
head off a deflationary spiral like that experienced in the 1930s. These
policies included sharply increasing the money supply and engaging in an
unprecedented amount of deficit spending.
In many ways the swift policy action
proved highly effective. Instead of the 25 percent unemployment
seen in the 1930s, joblessness reached only 10 percent. While unemployment now
stands at roughly eight percent, if one uses the labor force participation rate
from 2008, the level is still higher than 11 percent. Although there was a 3.5
percent decline in the price level between July and December of 2008, policymakers
immediately tackled and reversed the deflationary spiral. This compares with
the Great Depression, when between 1929 and 1933 the general price level
declined by 25 percent.
The Aftermath
Though some may be cheered by the relative
policy successes this time around, at the current trajectory it will still take
almost as long for total employment to fully recover as it did in the 1930s. While
job loss was not as severe this time, the recovery in job creation has been
much slower. Although nominal and real gross domestic production have returned
to new highs on a per capita basis, we are still below 2007 levels. In the same
way the Great Depression and the
depressions before it lasted eight to 10 years, we will likely continue to see
constrained economic growth until 2015-2016 (roughly nine years after U.S. home
prices began to slide). Only then will the excess inventory in the real estate
market be absorbed, allowing the plumbing of the financial system to function,
and supporting an increase in the economic growth rate.
At what cost did we attain this “success”? Like
any strong medicine, the policies pursued since 2008 have had, and are
continuing to have, unintended side effects. The most glaring feature of
today’s global landscape is that governments around the world have exhausted
their capacity to borrow money and have turned to their central banks to
provide unlimited credit. In the United States, it has taken an
average annual deficit of $1.2 trillion and multiple rounds of quantitative
easing just to keep the economy growing at a subpar rate since 2009.
In their 2009 book, This Time It’s Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly,
the economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff catalogue more than 250
financial crises and conclude that the U.S. cannot reasonably expect to
circumvent the outcome that has befallen all overleveraged nations. In the
authors’ words:
…Highly
leveraged economies, particularly those in which continual rollover of
short-term debt is sustained only by confidence in relatively illiquid
underlying assets, seldom survive forever, particularly if leverage continues
to grow unchecked.
Sovereign powers saddled with debt loads
as large as those of the U.S., Europe, and Japan today are jeopardizing their
long-term economic wellbeing.
In an October 2012 whitepaper, Reinhart and Rogoff
re-emphasized their findings that the U.S. cannot expect to quickly emerge from
what occurred in 2008. They point out that 2008 was the first
systemic crisis in the U.S. since the 1930s so the consequences have been much
more significant than fall-outs from normal recessions.
What Comes Next?
The most important question for investors concerns how
public sector debt levels, which have risen exponentially over the past
half-decade, will ultimately be discharged. As Reinhart and
Rogoff discuss, there are three options to reducing debt levels. The first is
restructuring, also known as default. For obvious reasons this is painful and
typically avoided except under the most dire circumstances. Governments
can also pursue structural reform, which in today’s case would mean greater
austerity. Implementation of this would stand in stark
opposition to Keynes’s recommendation that the fiscal and monetary spigots be
kept open during hard times. Although tightening is arguably the best long-term
path, it appears unlikely that it will be the primary policy of choice in the
near future. The third method, toward which I see global central bankers
drifting, is to keep interest rates artificially low
and permit increasing levels of inflation in the economy.
Pushing down the cost of borrowing and
allowing the price level to rise is known as financial repression. The real value of debtors’ obligations is reduced by financially
repressive policies. Keynes warned of the dangers of inflation in his early
work, The Economic Consequences of the Peace, which presciently criticized the
harshness of the Treaty of Versailles:
...By a
continuing process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and
unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens … As inflation
proceeds and the real value of the currency fluctuates wildly, all permanent
relations between debtors and creditors, which form the ultimate foundation of
capitalism, become so utterly disordered as to be almost meaningless.
Keynes re-iterated his views in the mid-1940s when he
visited the United States and saw programs that were touted as Keynesian
although he viewed them as primarily inflationary.
Financial repression is nothing new. Between
the 1940s and the early 1980s, the United States reduced its national debt from
140 percent of GDP to just 30 percent while continuing to run sizable deficits.
The difference between then and now is the magnitude of the debt mountain on
the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet that will need to be eroded. A
subtle shift has begun in which policymakers are starting to think of inflation
as a policy tool rather than the byproduct of their actions.
Despite Keynes’ warnings, it appears that higher inflation will continue to be
the monetary tool of choice for central bankers tasked with cleaning up
sovereign balance sheets.
Investment Implications
The long-term downside of mounting inflationary
pressure will ultimately accrue to bondholders and income-oriented investors. The
case can be made that we are marching headlong into a generational bear-market
for bonds. During
the next decade, holders of Treasury and agency securities will likely realize
negative real returns. Despite this, these assets continue to trade at
extremely rich valuations. Exactly when the market will awaken to this anomaly
in securities pricing remains to be determined. The analogy I would use for the
current interest rate environment is that of a balloon being held underwater. When
the Fed withdraws from the market and allows interest rates to find their
economic level, the balloon will inevitably ascend.
If investors need to stay in fixed-income assets, they should
transition into shorter duration credit and floating-rate products like bank
loans and asset-backed securities. If duration targeting is a
concern for liability-matching purposes, adjustable-rate assets can be
barbelled with long-duration securities like corporate bonds or long duration
agency mortgage securities.Equities
and risk assets are likely to rise as the money supply grows.
Gold, as I discussed in my October 2012
Market Perspectives, “Return to Bretton Woods,” has significant upside and should be included in any portfolio
designed to preserve or grow wealth over the long-term. Depending
on the scale of the current round of quantitative easing and the decline in
confidence in fiat currencies, the price of an ounce of gold could easily
exceed $2,500 within a relatively short time frame and could ultimately trade
much higher.
The
World is Waiting
The Great Depression brought about the
Keynesian Revolution, complete with new analytical tools and
economic programs that have been relied upon for decades. The
efficacy of these tools and programs has slowly been eroded over the years as the accumulation of
policy actions has reduced the flexibility to deal with crises as we reach
budget constraints and stretch the Fed’s balance sheet beyond anything
previously imagined. Nations have exceeded their ability to finance themselves
without relying on their central banks as lenders of last resort and
increasingly large doses of monetary policy are required just to keep the
economy expanding at a subpar pace. Some have referred to this as reaching
the Keynesian endpoint.
Keynes would barely recognize where we now
find ourselves. In this ultra loose policy environment we
are limited by our Keynesian toolkit. Today, the world is waiting for someone
to come forward and explain how we are going to get out of our current circumstances
without suffering the unintended consequences created by so-called Keynesian
policies.
Early in his life, Abraham Lincoln wrote that he
regretted not having been present during the founding of the nation because
that was when all the positions in the pantheon of great American leaders were
filled. By resolving America’s Imperial Crisis
through the Civil War and the abolishment of slavery, Lincoln would go on to
join those lofty ranks himself. Much like that crisis needed Lincoln, the
current crisis needs someone who can identify new tools to resolve the present
economic crisis. Until
then we are condemned to a path which leads to further currency debasement and
the erosion of purchasing power, with the result being a massive transfer of
wealth from creditor to debtor. Without a new economic paradigm, the
deleterious consequences of the current misguided policies are a foregone
conclusion. It
would seem my Dad could hardly have been more correct when he described the
next depression from behind the wheel of his 1969 Buick.
No comments:
Post a Comment