The Christmas and New Year's break, when Europe
shuts down and stops thinking, is now well and truly over, and we are
reawakening to the same old problems: Greece, Spain, Cyprus, Portugal, Italy,
France…all with their hands out for money from Germany, Holland, Finland, and
Austria.
The holiday from the banking crisis, which was
the result of the determination of the ECB to put a lid on it, is also over,
with yields on the supplicant countries’ debt rising again.
However, joining the bad news list is
the United Kingdom. Ominously, the pound is sliding in the foreign exchange
markets, providing a very tricky background for Chancellor Osborne’s budget on
March 20th. I shall examine the UK’s position later, but first let’s
update ourselves on developments in the Eurozone.
The reality is that all the problems of the
Eurozone are still with us, despite the fall in bond yields and their modest
subsequent recovery. There is now the likelihood that we are about to
enter the final phase of the end of the Eurozone experiment, with far wider
consequences. So we need to pick up the story where we left off.
First, let’s look at the trend of
government-debt-to-GDP for selected countries (the numbers are from the ECB):
As we can see, government deficits for these
countries took off from the time of the banking crisis and are still increasing
beyond the charts’ cut-off point into 2012. They reflect poor economic
performance, a lack of desire to slash government spending, and contracting
bank credit. Only Spain and France were below Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff’s
tipping point of 90% government debt-to-GDP (see their book, This Time
is Different), but in Spain’s case for 2012, if you add in €27bn raised to
pay the backlog of bills incurred by regional governments and the €40bn so far
(and rising) to bail out the mortgage banks, today Spain is closer to 100% debt
to GDP, and France’s is now over 90%.
Bank credit continues to be withdrawn by
European cross-border lenders, as the figures from the Bank for International
Settlements, which run from the time of the banking crisis, show in the next
chart:
This is a deflating credit bubble. Italy, France, and Ireland have seen the largest withdrawals. Italy has been pursuing aggressive tax collection, driving wealth abroad and deterring economic activity, Ireland has seen a contraction in its financial centre, but France is the surprise suggesting that deflationary forces are stronger than generally understood. The decline in bank lending from European banks has been compensated for by generous Americans, presumably too-big-to-fail banks on instruction from the Fed, putting up an extra $850bn in the first three quarters of 2009. Meanwhile, UK banks have maintained business as usual, slightly increasing their exposure from 2009 onwards. This is shown in the next chart.
Of course, domestic bank lending in all of these
countries, with the possible exception of France, has equally been constrained
by capital flight from domestic banks, reflected in TARGET2 balances building
up in Germany, Netherlands, Luxembourg, and Finland, as shown in the next
chart.
This capital flight has come from the other
countries on this chart, and interestingly, there is early evidence that money
is now leaving France.
Overall the pressure has come off these
imbalances, the natural consequence of a pause in the flow of bad news perhaps,
and reflecting the ECB’s success in bringing back a degree of stability. This
is also reflected in the next chart, which groups central bank loans to credit
institutions in the weak, the strong, and others:
We can clearly see the effect of last year’s
crisis on the GIIPS banks, but there is also a worrying pick-up in France,
which makes up the bulk of “others”.
This quick tour of European statistics sets the
scene. It is clear that some short-term stability has returned, but there is
not enough evidence that the underlying position has actually changed. One
should bear in mind that European politicians and their economic advisers, with
very few exceptions, do not understand markets, and believe that they mostly
require confidence. While there is some short-term truth in this belief as
recent market performance suggests, the European political establishment
appears to go further, believing that confidence is everything. The
current economic strategy is therefore little more substantive than to talk
markets up.
The reality behind this short-term façade is
very different. As time marches on, government employees have to be paid and
welfare distributed. Those combined government deficits for the Eurozone need
feeding by extra taxes and borrowing at the rate of $40bn per month and rising.
And this is only part of the story; along with as central governments, regional
governments, cities, and towns (particularly in the periphery) are in deep
trouble and have even suspended salaries for employees such as doctors and
teachers, as well as payments for essential services.
General government in the Eurozone (which for
statistical purposes includes regional and local governments) takes up
approximately 50% of GDP. This is the Eurozone’s weakness: The
productive capacity of its economy is overwhelmed by the burden of too much
government.
Now go back to the first chart, showing the
trend of government-debt-to-GDP for selected countries, and worry. It is
indicative not only of the suffocating burden of government debt, but because
government dominates individual economies, it is also tells us that their
private sectors cannot backstop this debt through future taxes.
Therefore there’s no way economic recovery will
provide the get-out-of-jail card for the weaker group of countries. The
transfer of wealth from a relatively limited private sector to high-spending
governments is no solution, as France has found out. If you raise taxes to
balance the books, taxpayers walk.
Welfare Costs
No one in Europe mentions escalating welfare
costs. So far as I am aware, there are no estimates for the net present value
of future welfare costs for Eurozone countries, such as the one by Professor
Kotlikoff of Boston University for the United States. The element of
“baby-boomers” in European demographics varies, but the state pensions,
healthcare costs, and other benefits are very high, as shown in the following
table (data mostly supplied by the OECD “Pensions at a glance 2011”).
Over the last year, pension costs as a proportion of GDP will have risen above
these figures due to the increasing retirement rate, and even more sharply in
those countries where GDP has fallen. These figures will therefore be
under-estimates for the current position.
We know from Professor Kotlikoff’s estimates
that the net present value of the US’s future welfare costs rose $11 trillion
in 2012, we also know that free healthcare in the eurozone is more advanced –
meaning more expensive - than in the US. With the eurozone’s public pension
costs on average nearly twice that of the US, we can see that the
baby-boomer and longevity problems faced by the United States are nothing
compared with key Eurozone countries. It is also important to note that the
cost on government finances of a retiring wage-earner is two-fold: The state
loses tax revenue and gains a cost.
The only Eurozone countries in the table with
lower pension costs are Ireland and the Netherlands, both smaller population
countries. Furthermore, all Eurozone countries, with the exception of Ireland,
have a higher proportion of pensioners than the OECD average, implying again
that future welfare costs are substantially greater than those of the U.S.
The level of unemployment (the last column) must
be taken into account as well, because an unemployed person does not pay the
taxes to fund pensions. The countries with a high level of unemployment and
higher-than-average numbers of pensioners as a proportion of the working
population are in deep trouble. The worst, in descending order, are Greece,
Italy, Spain, Portugal, and France. Furthermore, Spain, and Ireland have raided
their public pension funds to support general government finances.
We can therefore conclude that even if somehow
the Eurozone extracts itself from its current difficulties it will have to
address the burden of these future welfare costs as a matter of urgency.
While on the subject of welfare and pensions, it
is worth mentioning the impact on Scandinavian countries with their
exceptionally high taxes, which vary from Norway’s 57.9% of GDP to Sweden’s
51.4%. These countries, which everyone assumes are financially stable, will be
badly hit by the demographic time-bomb.
So far, welfare has not been a headline issue
anywhere and until fairly recently politicians have stayed off the subject.
However, it is now being recognised as a growing problem to which there is no
easy solution. Properly accounted for with reasonable provisions made, it is
obvious that including the net present value of these future commitments true
government deficits are multiples higher than officially stated.
Eurozone Politics
The political balance has changed substantially
over the last year, from the cosy days when Merkel met Sarkozy and Monti kept
the Italians in order. First, Sarkozy was dumped by the French electorate,
which preferred welfare to austerity, and now Monti has been dumped for similar
reasons. The idea that Chancellor Merkel can trade greater fiscal control over
the Eurozone debtors for her own electoral support in Germany has been
disproved. The ramifications of the hung Parliament in Rome are likely to be
profound, not least in Berlin.
Germany faces full elections in September this
year, and it will be difficult for Chancellor Merkel to win, given that her
party, the Christian Democrats, did badly in the local German elections in
January. The German voter has generally been more concerned with Germany’s
relative economic success, bringing low unemployment, than the intractable
problem of supporting other Eurozone nations. This may be changing, with
Germany’s more dynamic export markets – China, Russia, and the
other emerging economies – slowing somewhat. If this trend
continues and unemployment rises, the Christian Democrats will find it a
struggle to get re-elected.
For this reason, it is likely that Merkel’s room
for manoeuvre will be increasingly limited. It is apparent to the German voter
that the government has no prospect of recovering money lent to the Eurozone
periphery through the banks, reflected in TARGET2 balances, nor directly
through the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). So far, the ESM has only lent
€40bn to Spain to recapitalise the Spanish mortgage banks, but the demands on
the ESM are bound to increase. Germany’s contribution to date is €21.72bn, which
can be increased, if required, to €190bn.
Given Merkel’s political difficulties, she is
likely to be slow to subscribe Germany’s full commitment and can use the excuse
that she can only be expected to match the other large contributors – who
are by the way, France, Italy, and Spain. It is likely to be a political virtue
for her to take a tougher line.
It would therefore be a mistake to think that
Germany is going to continue to fund profligate governments. Since the ECB has
already created the precedent (quote from Mr Draghi: “Whatever it takes”),
the ECB will have to end up creating the money required.
We conclude therefore that the
Eurozone is now on track for a hyper-inflationary outcome, rather than a
deflationary collapse, similar to prospects for the other major currencies.
Its collective banking system is also extremely vulnerable to shocks with accumulated
bad debts from prior bubbles and prospective bad debts from insolvent
government debts.
To understand how this will play out, one needs
to understand the likely future in store for each of the most unfluential,
unstable players in this unfolding melodrama: Spain, Italy, France – and
a recent addition, the UK.
No comments:
Post a Comment