By RON UNZ
During the three decades following Deng Xiaoping’s 1978 reforms, China
achieved the fastest sustained rate of economic growth in human history, with
the resulting 40-fold rise in the size of China’s economy leaving it poised to
surpass America’s as the largest in the world. A billion ordinary Han Chinese
have lifted themselves economically from oxen and bicycles to the verge of
automobiles within a single generation.
China’s academic performance has been just as stunning. The 2009 Program
for International Student Assessment (PISA)
tests placed gigantic Shanghai—a megalopolis of 15 million—at the absolute top
of world student achievement.1 PISA
results from the rest of the country have been nearly as impressive, with the
average scores of hundreds of millions of provincial Chinese—mostly from rural
families with annual incomes below $2,000—matching or exceeding those of
Europe’s most advanced and successful countries, such as Germany, France, and
Switzerland, and ranking well above America’s results.2
These successes follow closely on the heels of a previous generation of
similar economic and technological gains for several much smaller
Chinese-ancestry countries in that same part of the world, such as Taiwan, Hong
Kong, and Singapore, and the great academic and socioeconomic success of small
Chinese-descended minority populations in predominantly white nations,
including America, Canada, and Australia. The children of the Yellow Emperor
seem destined to play an enormous role in Mankind’s future.
Although
these developments might have shocked Westerners of the mid-20th Century—when
China was best known for its terrible poverty and Maoist revolutionary
fanaticism—they would have seemed far less unexpected to our leading thinkers
of 100 years ago, many of whom prophesied that the Middle Kingdom would
eventually regain its ranking among the foremost nations of the world. This was
certainly the expectation of A.E. Ross, one of America’s greatest early
sociologists, whose book The Changing Chinese looked past the destitution, misery,
and corruption of the China of his day to a future modernized China perhaps on
a technological par with America and the leading European nations. Ross’s views
were widely echoed by public intellectuals such as Lothrop Stoddard, who foresaw
China’s probable awakening from centuries of inward-looking slumber as a
looming challenge to the worldwide hegemony long enjoyed by the various
European-descended nations.
The likely roots of such widespread Chinese success have received little
detailed exploration in today’s major Western media, which tends to shy away
from considering the particular characteristics of ethnic groups or
nationalities, as opposed to their institutional systems and forms of
government. Yet although the latter obviously play a crucial role—Maoist China
was far less economically successful than Dengist China—it is useful to note
that the examples of Chinese success cited above range across a wide diversity
of socioeconomic/political systems.
For
decades, Hong Kong enjoyed one of the most free-market, nearly
anarcho-libertarian economic systems; during that same period, Singapore was
governed by the tight hand of Lee Kuan Yew and his socialistic People’s Action
Party, which built a one-party state with a large degree of government guidance
and control. Yet both these populations were overwhelmingly Chinese, and both
experienced almost equally rapid economic development, moving in 50 years from
total postwar destitution and teeming refugee slums to ranking among the
wealthiest places on earth. And Taiwan, whose much larger Chinese-ancestry
population pursued an intermediate development model, enjoyed similar economic
success.
Despite a
long legacy of racial discrimination and mistreatment, small Chinese
communities in America also prospered and advanced, even as their numbers grew
rapidly following passage of the 1965 Immigration Act. In recent years a
remarkable fraction of America’s top students—whether judged by the objective
winners’ circle of the Mathematics Olympiad and Intel Science competition or by
the somewhat more subjective rates of admission to Ivy League colleges—have
been of Chinese ancestry. The results are particularly striking when cast in
quantitative terms: although just 1 percent of American high-school graduates
each year have ethnic Chinese origins, surname analysis indicates that they
currently include nearly 15 percent of the highest-achieving students, a
performance ratio more than four times better than that of American Jews, the
top-scoring white ancestry group.3 Chinese
people seem to be doing extremely well all over the world, across a wide range
of economic and cultural landscapes.
Almost
none of these global developments were predicted by America’s leading
intellectuals of the 1960s or 1970s, and many of their successors have had just
as much difficulty recognizing the dramatic sweep of events through which they
are living. A perfect example of this strange myopia may be found in the
writings of leading development economists Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson,
whose brief discussions of China’s rapid rise to world economic dominance seem
to portray the phenomenon as a temporary illusion almost certain soon to
collapse because the institutional approach followed differs from the
ultra-free-market neoliberalism that they recommend.4 The
large role that the government plays in guiding Chinese economic decisions
dooms it to failure, despite all evidence to the contrary, while America’s
heavily financialized economy must be successful, regardless of our high
unemployment and low growth. According to Acemoglu and Robinson, nearly all
international success or failure is determined by governmental institutions,
and since China possesses the wrong ones, failure is certain, though there
seems no sign of it.
Perhaps
such academics will be proven correct, and China’s economic miracle will
collapse into the debacle they predict. But if this does not occur, and the
international trend lines of the past 35 years continue for another five or
ten, we should consider turning for explanations to those long-forgotten
thinkers who actually foretold these world developments that we are now
experiencing, individuals such as Ross and Stoddard. The widespread devastation
produced by the Japanese invasion, World War II, and the Chinese Civil War,
followed by the economic calamity of Maoism, did delay the predicted rise of
China by a generation or two, but except for such unforeseen events, their
analysis of Chinese potential seems remarkably prescient. For example, Stoddard
approvingly quotes the late Victorian predictions of Professor Charles E.
Pearson:
Does any one doubt that the day is at hand when China will have cheap fuel from her coal-mines, cheap transport by railways and steamers, and will have founded technical schools to develop her industries? Whenever that day comes, she may wrest the control of the world’s markets, especially throughout Asia, from England and Germany.5
A
People Shaped by Their Difficult Environment
Western
intellectual life a century ago was quite different from that of today, with
contrary doctrines and taboos, and the spirit of that age certainly held sway
over its leading figures. Racialism—the notion that different peoples tend to
have different innate traits, as largely fashioned by their particular
histories—was dominant then, so much so that the notion was almost universally
held and applied, sometimes in rather crude fashion, to both European and
non-European populations.
With regard to the Chinese, the widespread view was that many of their prominent characteristics had been shaped by thousands of years of history in a generally stable and organized society possessing central political administration, a situation almost unique among the peoples of the world. In effect, despite temporary periods of political fragmentation, East Asia’s own Roman Empire had never fallen, and a thousand-year interregnum of barbarism, economic collapse, and technological backwardness had been avoided.
With regard to the Chinese, the widespread view was that many of their prominent characteristics had been shaped by thousands of years of history in a generally stable and organized society possessing central political administration, a situation almost unique among the peoples of the world. In effect, despite temporary periods of political fragmentation, East Asia’s own Roman Empire had never fallen, and a thousand-year interregnum of barbarism, economic collapse, and technological backwardness had been avoided.
On the
less fortunate side, the enormous population growth of recent centuries had
gradually caught up with and overtaken China’s exceptionally efficient
agricultural system, reducing the lives of most Chinese to the brink of
Malthusian starvation; and these pressures and constraints were believed to be
reflected in the Chinese people. For example, Stoddard wrote:
Winnowed by ages of grim elimination in a land populated to the uttermost limits of subsistence, the Chinese race is selected as no other for survival under the fiercest conditions of economic stress. At home the average Chinese lives his whole life literally within a hand’s breadth of starvation. Accordingly, when removed to the easier environment of other lands, the Chinaman brings with him a working capacity which simply appalls his competitors.6
Stoddard
backed these riveting phrases with a wide selection of detailed and descriptive
quotations from prominent observers, both Western and Chinese. Although Ross
was more cautiously empirical in his observations and less literary in his
style, his analysis was quite similar, with his book on the Chinese containing
over 40 pages describing the grim and gripping details of daily survival,
provided under the evocative chapter-heading “The Struggle for Existence in
China.”7
During the
second half of the 20th century, ideological considerations largely eliminated
from American public discourse the notion that many centuries of particular
circumstances might leave an indelible imprint upon a people. But with the turn
of the new millennium, such analyses have once again begun appearing in
respectable intellectual quarters.
The most
notable example of this would surely be A Farewell to Alms, Gregory
Clark’s fascinating 2007 analysis of the deep origins of Britain’s industrial
revolution, which was widely reviewed and praised throughout elite circles,
with New York Timeseconomics columnist Tyler Cowen
hailing it as possibly “the next blockbuster in economics” and Berkeley
economist Brad DeLong characterizing it as “brilliant.”
Although
Clark’s work focused on many different factors, the one that attracted the
greatest attention was his demographic analysis of British history based upon a
close examination of individual testaments. Clark discovered evidence that for
centuries the wealthier British had left significantly more surviving children
than their poorer compatriots, thus leading their descendents to constitute an
ever larger share of each generation. Presumably, this was because they could
afford to marry at a younger age, and their superior nutritional and living
arrangements reduced mortality rates for themselves and their families. Indeed,
the near-Malthusian poverty of much ordinary English life during this era meant
that the impoverished lower classes often failed even to reproduce themselves
over time, gradually being replaced by the downwardly mobile children of their
financial betters. Since personal economic achievement was probably in part due
to traits such as diligence, prudence, and productivity, Clark argued that
these characteristics steadily became more widespread in the British
population, laying the human basis for later national economic success.
Leaving
aside whether or not the historical evidence actually supports Clark’s
hypothesis—economist Robert C. Allen has published a strong and fairly
persuasive refutation8—the theoretical framework he advances
seems a perfectly plausible one. Although the stylistic aspects and
quantitative approaches certainly differ, much of Clark’s analysis for England
seems to have clear parallels in how Stoddard, Ross, and others of their era
characterized China. So perhaps it would be useful to explore whether a
Clarkian analysis might be applicable to the people of the Middle Kingdom.
Interestingly
enough, Clark himself devotes a few pages to considering this question and
concludes that in contrast to the British case, wealthier Chinese were no more
fecund than the poorer, eliminating the possibility of any similar generational
trend.9But Clark is not a China specialist, and
his brief analysis relies on the birth records of the descendents of the ruling
imperial dynasty, a group totally unrepresentative of the broader population.
In fact, a more careful examination of the Chinese source material reveals
persuasive evidence for a substantial skew in family size, directly related to
economic success, with the pattern being perhaps even stronger and more
universally apparent than was the case for Britain or any other country.
Moreover,
certain unique aspects of traditional Chinese society may have maintained and
amplified this long-term effect, in a manner unlike that found in most other
societies in Europe or elsewhere. China indeed may constitute the largest and
longest-lasting instance of an extreme “Social Darwinist” society anywhere in
human history, perhaps with important implications for the shaping of the
modern Chinese people.10
The
Social Economy of Traditional China
Chinese
society is notable for its stability and longevity. From the gradual
establishment of the bureaucratic imperial state based on mandarinate rule
during the Sui (589–618) and T’ang (618–907) dynasties down to the Communist
Revolution of 1948, a single set of social and economic relations appears to
have maintained its grip on the country, evolving only slightly while dynastic
successions and military conquests periodically transformed the governmental
superstructure.
A central
feature of this system was the replacement of the local rule of aristocratic
elements by a class of official meritocrats, empowered by the central
government and selected by competitive examination. In essence, China
eliminated the role of hereditary feudal lords and the social structure they
represented over 1,000 years before European countries did the same,
substituting a system of legal equality for virtually the entire population
beneath the reigning emperor and his family.
The social
importance of competitive examinations was enormous, playing the same role in
determining membership in the ruling elite that the aristocratic bloodlines of
Europe’s nobility did until modern times, and this system embedded itself just
as deeply in the popular culture. The great noble houses of France or Germany
might trace their lineages back to ancestors elevated under Charlemagne or
Barbarossa, with their heirs afterward rising and falling in standing and
estates, while in China the proud family traditions would boast generations of
top-scoring test-takers, along with the important government positions that
they had received as a result. Whereas in Europe there existed fanciful stories
of a heroic commoner youth doing some great deed for the king and consequently
being elevated to a knighthood or higher, such tales were confined to fiction
down to the French Revolution. But in China, even the greatest lineages of
academic performers almost invariably had roots in the ordinary peasantry.
Not only
was China the first national state to utilize competitive written examinations
for selection purposes, but it is quite possible that almost all other
instances everywhere in the world ultimately derive from the Chinese example.
It has long been established that the Chinese system served as the model for
the meritocratic civil services that transformed the efficiency of Britain and
other European states during the 18th and 19th centuries. But persuasive
historical arguments have also been advanced that the same is even true for
university entrance tests and honors examinations, with Cambridge’s famed Math
Tripos being the earliest example.11 Modern
written tests may actually be as Chinese as chopsticks.
With
Chinese civilization having spent most of the past 1,500 years allocating its
positions of national power and influence by examination, there has sometimes
been speculation that test-taking ability has become embedded in the Chinese
people at the biological as well as cultural level. Yet although there might be
an element of truth to this, it hardly seems likely to be significant. During
the eras in question, China’s total population numbered far into the tens of millions,
growing in unsteady fashion from perhaps 60 million before AD 900 to well over
400 million by 1850. But the number of Chinese passing the highest imperial
exam and attaining the exalted rank of chin-shihduring most of the
past six centuries was often less than 100 per year, down from a high of over
200 under the Sung dynasty (960-1279), and even if we include the lesser rank
of chu-jen, the national total of such
degree-holders was probably just in the low tens of thousands,12 a
tiny fraction of 1 percent of the overall population—totally dwarfed by the
numbers of Chinese making their living as artisans or merchants, let alone the
overwhelming mass of the rural peasantry. The cultural impact of rule by a
test-selected elite was enormous, but the direct genetic impact would have been
negligible.
This same
difficulty of relative proportions frustrates any attempt to apply in China an
evolutionary model similar to the one that Gregory Cochran and Henry Harpending
have persuasively suggested for the evolution of high intelligence among the
Ashkenazi Jews of Europe.13 The
latter group constituted a small, reproductively isolated population
overwhelmingly concentrated in the sorts of business and financial activity
that would have strongly favored more intelligent individuals, and one with
insignificant gene-flow from the external population not undergoing such
selective pressure. By contrast, there is no evidence that successful Chinese
merchants or scholars were unwilling to take brides from the general
population, and any reasonable rate of such intermarriage each generation would
have totally swamped the selective impact of mercantile or scholarly success.
If we are hoping to find any rough parallel to the process that Clark
hypothesizes for Britain, we must concentrate our attention on the life
circumstances of China’s broad rural peasantry—well over 90 percent of the
population during all these centuries—just as the aforementioned 19th-century
observers generally had done.
Absence
of Caste and Fluidity of Class
In fact,
although Western observers tended to focus on China’s horrific poverty above
all else, traditional Chinese society actually possessed certain unusual or
even unique characteristics that may help account for the shaping of the
Chinese people. Perhaps the most important of these was the near total absence
of social caste and the extreme fluidity of economic class.
Feudalism
had ended in China a thousand years before the French Revolution, and nearly
all Chinese stood equal before the law.14 The
“gentry”—those who had passed an official examination and received an academic
degree—possessed certain privileges and the “mean people”—prostitutes,
entertainers, slaves, and various other degraded social elements—suffered under
legal discrimination. But both these strata were minute in size, with each
usually amounting to less than 1 percent of the general population, while “the
common people”—everyone else, including the peasantry—enjoyed complete legal
equality.
However,
such legal equality was totally divorced from economic equality, and extreme
gradations of wealth and poverty were found in every corner of society, down to
the smallest and most homogenous village. During most of the 20th century, the
traditional Marxian class analysis of Chinese rural life divided the population
according to graduated wealth and degree of “exploitative” income: landlords,
who obtained most or all of their income from rent or hired labor; rich,
middle, and poor peasants, grouped according to decreasing wealth and rental
income and increasing tendency to hire out their own labor; and agricultural
laborers, who owned negligible land and obtained nearly all their income from
hiring themselves out to others.
In hard
times, these variations in wealth might easily mean the difference between life
and death, but everyone acknowledged that such distinctions were purely
economic and subject to change: a landlord who lost his land would become a
poor peasant; a poor peasant who came into wealth would be the equal of any
landlord. During its political struggle, the Chinese Communist Party claimed
that landlords and rich peasants constituted about 10 percent of the population
and possessed 70–80 percent of the land, while poor peasants and hired laborers
made up the overwhelming majority of the population and owned just 10–15
percent of the land. Neutral observers found these claims somewhat exaggerated
for propagandistic purposes, but not all that far from the harsh reality.15
Complete
legal equality and extreme economic inequality together fostered one of the
most unrestrained free-market systems known to history, not only in China’s
cities but much more importantly in its vast countryside, which contained
nearly the entire population. Land, the primary form of wealth, was freely
bought, sold, traded, rented out, sub-leased, or mortgaged as loan collateral.
Money-lending and food-lending were widely practiced, especially during times
of famine, with usurious rates of interest being the norm, often in excess of
10 percent per month compounded. In extreme cases, children or even wives might
be sold for cash and food. Unless aided by relatives, peasants without land or
money routinely starved to death. Meanwhile, the agricultural activity of more
prosperous peasants was highly commercialized and entrepreneurial, with complex
business arrangements often the norm.16
For
centuries, a central fact of daily life in rural China had been the tremendous
human density, as the Middle Kingdom’s population expanded from 65 million to
430 million during the five centuries before 1850,17 eventually
forcing nearly all land to be cultivated to maximum efficiency. Although
Chinese society was almost entirely rural and agricultural, Shandong province
in 1750 had well over twice the population density of the Netherlands, the most
urbanized and densely populated part of Europe, while during the early years of
the Industrial Revolution, England’s population density was only one-fifth that
of Jiangsu province.18
Chinese
agricultural methods had always been exceptionally efficient, but by the 19th
century, the continuing growth of the Chinese population had finally caught and
surpassed the absolute Malthusian carrying-capacity of the farming system under
its existing technical and economic structure.19 Population
growth was largely held in check by mortality (including high infant
mortality), decreased fertility due to malnutrition, disease, and periodic
regional famines that killed an average of 5 percent of the population.20 Even
the Chinese language came to incorporate the centrality of food, with the
traditional words of greeting being “Have you eaten?” and the common phrase
denoting a wedding, funeral, or other important social occasion being “to eat
good things.”21
The
cultural and ideological constraints of Chinese society posed major obstacles
to mitigating this never-ending human calamity. Although impoverished Europeans
of this era, male and female alike, often married late or not at all, early
marriage and family were central pillars of Chinese life, with the sage Mencius
stating that to have no children was the worst of unfilial acts; indeed,
marriage and anticipated children were the mark of adulthood. Furthermore, only
male heirs could continue the family name and ensure that oneself and one’s
ancestors would be paid the proper ritual respect, and multiple sons were
required to protect against the vagaries of fate. On a more practical level,
married daughters became part of their husband’s household, and only sons could
ensure provision for one’s old age.
Nearly all
peasant societies sanctify filial loyalty, marriage, family, and children,
while elevating sons above daughters, but in traditional China these tendencies
seem to have been especially strong, representing a central goal and focus of
all daily life beyond bare survival. Given the terrible poverty, cruel choices
were often made, and female infanticide, including through neglect, was the
primary means of birth control among the poor, leading to a typical shortfall
of 10–15 percent among women of marriageable age. Reproductive competition for
those remaining women was therefore fierce, with virtually every woman
marrying, generally by her late teens. The inevitable result was a large and
steady natural increase in the total population, except when constrained by
various forms of increased mortality.
Remarkable
Upward Mobility But Relentless Downward Mobility
The vast
majority of Chinese might be impoverished peasants, but for those with ability
and luck, the possibilities of upward mobility were quite remarkable in what
was an essentially classless society. The richer strata of each village
possessed the wealth to give their most able children a classical education in
hopes of preparing them for the series of official examinations. If the son of
a rich peasant or petty landlord were sufficiently diligent and intellectually
able, he might pass such an examination and obtain an official degree, opening
enormous opportunities for political power and wealth.
For the
Ming (1368–1644) and Ch’ing (1644–1911) dynasties, statistics exist on the
social origins of the chin-shih class, the highest official rank, and
these demonstrate a rate of upward mobility unmatched by almost any Western
society, whether modern or premodern. Over 30 percent of such elite
degree-holders came from commoner families that for three previous generations
had produced no one of high official rank, and in the data from earlier
centuries, this fraction of “new men” reached a high of 84 percent. Such
numbers far exceed the equivalent figures for Cambridge University during all
the centuries since its foundation, and would probably seem remarkable at
America’s elite Ivy League colleges today or in the past. Meanwhile, downward
social mobility was also common among even the highest families. As a summary
statistic, across the six centuries of these two dynasties less than 6 percent
of China’s ruling elites came from the ruling elites of the previous generation.22
The
founding philosophical principle of the modern Western world has been the
“Equality of Man,” while that of Confucianist China was the polar opposite
belief in the inherent inequality of men. Yet in reality, the latter often
seemed to fulfill better the ideological goals of the former. Frontier America
might have had its mythos of presidents born in log-cabins, but for many
centuries a substantial fraction of the Middle Kingdom’s ruling mandarins did
indeed come from rural rice-paddies, a state of affairs that would have seemed
almost unimaginable in any European country until the Age of Revolution, and
even long afterward.
Such
potential for elevation into the ruling Chinese elite was remarkable, but a far
more important factor in the society was the open possibility of local economic
advancement for the sufficiently enterprising and diligent rural peasant.
Ironically enough, a perfect description of such upward mobility was provided
by Communist revolutionary leader Mao Zedong, who recounted how his father had
risen from being a landless poor peasant to rich peasant status:
My father was a poor peasant and while still young was obliged to join the army because of heavy debts. He was a soldier for many years. Later on he returned to the village where I was born, and by saving carefully and gathering together a little money through small trading and other enterprise he managed to buy back his land.
As middle peasants then my family owned fifteen mou [about 2.5 acres] of land. On this they could raise sixty tan of rice a year. The five members of the family consumed a total of thirty-five tan—that is, about seven each—which left an annual surplus of twenty-five tan. Using this surplus, my father accumulated a little capital and in time purchased seven more mou, which gave the family the status of ‘rich’ peasants. We could ten raise eighty-four tan of rice a year.
When I was ten years of age and the family owned only fifteen mou of land, the five members of the family consisted of my father, mother, grandfather, younger brother, and myself. After we had acquired the additional seven mou, my grandfather died, but there came another younger brother. However, we still had a surplus of forty-nine tan of rice each year, and on this my father prospered.
At the time my father was a middle peasant he began to deal in grain transport and selling, by which he made a little money. After he became a ‘rich’ peasant, he devoted most of his time to that business. He hired a full-time farm laborer, and put his children to work on the farm, as well as his wife. I began to work at farming tasks when I was six years old. My father had no shop for his business. He simply purchased grain from the poor farmers and then transported it to the city merchants, where he got a higher price. In the winter, when the rice was being ground, he hired an extra laborer to work on the farm, so that at that time there were seven mouths to feed. My family ate frugally, but had enough always.23
Mao’s
account gives no indication that he regarded his family’s rise as extraordinary
in any way; his father had obviously done well, but there were probably many
other families in Mao’s village that had similarly improved their lot during
the course of a single generation. Such opportunities for rapid social mobility
would have been almost impossible in any of the feudal or class-ridden
societies of the same period, in Europe or most other parts of the world.
However,
the flip-side of possible peasant upward mobility was the far greater
likelihood of downward mobility, which was enormous and probably represented
the single most significant factor shaping the modern Chinese people. Each
generation, a few who were lucky or able might rise, but a vast multitude
always fell, and those families near the bottom simply disappeared from the
world. Traditional rural China was a society faced with the reality of an
enormous and inexorable downward mobility: for centuries, nearly all Chinese
ended their lives much poorer than had their parents.
The strong
case for such downward mobility was demonstrated a quarter century ago by
historian Edwin E. Moise,24 whose
crucial article on the subject has received far less attention than it
deserves, perhaps because the intellectual climate of the late 1970s prevented
readers from drawing the obvious evolutionary implications.
In many
respects, Moise’s demographic analysis of China eerily anticipated that of
Clark for England, as he pointed out that only the wealthier families of a
Chinese village could afford the costs associated with obtaining wives for
their sons, with female infanticide and other factors regularly ensuring up to
a 15 percent shortfall in the number of available women. Thus, the poorest
village strata usually failed to reproduce at all, while poverty and
malnourishment also tended to lower fertility and raise infant mortality as one
moved downward along the economic gradient. At the same time, the wealthiest
villagers sometimes could afford multiple wives or concubines and regularly
produced much larger numbers of surviving offspring. Each generation, the
poorest disappeared, the less affluent failed to replenish their numbers, and
all those lower rungs on the economic ladder were filled by the downwardly
mobile children of the fecund wealthy.
This
fundamental reality of Chinese rural existence was certainly obvious to the
peasants themselves and to outside observers, and there exists an enormous
quantity of anecdotal evidence describing the situation, whether gathered by
Moise or found elsewhere, as illustrated by a few examples:
‘How could any man in our village claim that his family had been poor for three generations? If a man is poor, then his son can’t afford to marry; and if his son can’t marry, there can’t be a third generation.’25
… Because of the marked shortage of women, there was always a great number of men without wives at all. This included the overwhelming majority of long-term hired laborers… The poorest families died out, being unable to arrange marriages for their sons. The future generations of poor were the descendants of bankrupted middle and rich peasants and landlords.26
… Further down the economic scale there were many families with unmarried sons who had already passed the customary marriage age, thus limiting the size of the family. Wong Mi was a case in point. He was already twenty-three, with both of his parents in their mid-sixties; but since the family was able to rent only an acre of poor land and could not finance his marriage, he lived with the old parents, and the family consisted of three members. Wong Chun, a landless peasant in his forties, had been in the same position when he lived with his aged parents ten years before, and now, both parents having died, he lived alone. There were ten or fifteen families in the village with single unmarried sons.27
… As previously mentioned, there were about twenty families in Nanching that had no land at all and constituted the bottom group in the village’s pyramid of land ownership. A few of these families were tenant farmers, but the majority, since they could not finance even the buying of tools, fertilizer, and seeds, worked as “long-term” agricultural laborers on an annual basis. As such, they normally were paid about 1,000 catties of unhusked rice per year and board and room if they owned no home. This income might equal or even exceed what they might have wrested from a small rented farm, but it was not enough to support a family of average size without supplementary employment undertaken by other members of the family. For this reason, many of them never married, and the largest number of bachelors was to be found among landless peasants. Wong Tu-en, a landless peasant working for a rich peasant for nearly ten years, was still a “bare stick” (unmarried man) in his fifties; and there were others in the village like him. They were objects of ridicule and pity in the eyes of the villagers, whose life [sic] centered upon the family.28
Furthermore,
the forces of downward mobility in rural Chinese society were greatly
accentuated by fenjia, the traditional
system of inheritance, which required equal division of property among all
sons, in sharp contrast to the practice of primogeniture commonly found in
European countries.
If most or
all of a father’s property went to the eldest son, then the long-term survival
of a reasonably affluent peasant family was assured unless the primary heir
were a complete wastrel or encountered unusually bad fortune. But in China,
cultural pressures forced a wealthy man to do his best to maximize the number
of his surviving sons, and within the richer strata of a village it was not
uncommon for a man to leave two, three, or even more male heirs, compelling
each to begin his economic independence with merely a fraction of his father’s
wealth. Unless they succeeded in substantially augmenting their inheritance,
the sons of a particularly fecund rich landlord might be middle peasants—and
his grandchildren, starving poor peasants.29Families whose elevated status derived
from a single fortuitous circumstance or a transient trait not deeply rooted in
their behavioral characteristics therefore enjoyed only fleeting economic
success, and poverty eventually culled their descendents from the village.
The
members of a successful family could maintain their economic position over time
only if in each generation large amounts of additional wealth were extracted
from their land and their neighbors through high intelligence, sharp business
sense, hard work, and great diligence. The penalty for major business
miscalculations or lack of sufficient effort was either personal or
reproductive extinction. As American observer William Hinton graphically
described:
Security, relative comfort, influence, position, and leisure [were] maintained amidst a sea of the most dismal and frightening poverty and hunger—a poverty and hunger which at all times threatened to engulf any family which relaxed its vigilance, took pity on its poor neighbors, failed to extract the last copper of rent and interest, or ceased for an instant the incessant accumulation of grain and money. Those who did not go up went down, and those who went down often went to their deaths or at least to the dissolution and dispersal of their families.30
However,
under favorable circumstances, a family successful in business might expand its
numbers from generation to generation until it gradually squeezed out all its
less competitive neighbors, with its progeny eventually constituting nearly the
entire population of a village. For example, a century after a couple of poor
Yang brothers arrived in a region as farm laborers, their descendents had
formed a clan of 80–90 families in one village and the entire population of a
neighboring one.31 In a
Guangdong village, a merchant family named Huang arrived and bought land,
growing in numbers and land ownership over the centuries until their
descendants replaced most of the other families, which became poor and ultimately
disappeared, while the Huangs eventually constituted 74 percent of the total
local population, including a complete mix of the rich, middle, and poor.32
The
Implications for the Chinese People and for American Ideology
In many
respects, the Chinese society portrayed by our historical and sociological
sources seems an almost perfect example of the sort of local environment that
would be expected to produce a deep imprint upon the characteristics of its
inhabitants. Even prior to the start of this harsh development process, China
had spent thousands of years as one of the world’s most advanced economic and
technological civilizations. The socioeconomic system established from the end
of the sixth century A.D. onward then remained largely stable and unchanged for
well over a millennium, with the sort of orderly and law-based society that
benefited those who followed its rules and ruthlessly weeded out the
troublemaker. During many of those centuries, the burden of overpopulation
placed enormous economic pressure on each family to survive, while a powerful
cultural tradition emphasized the production of surviving offspring, especially
sons, as the greatest goal in life, even if that result might lead to the
impoverishment of the next generation. Agricultural efficiency was remarkably
high but required great effort and diligence, while the complexities of
economic decision-making—how to manage land, crop selection, and investment
decisions—were far greater than those faced by the simple peasant serf found in
most other parts of the world, with the rewards for success and the penalties
for failure being extreme. The sheer size and cultural unity of the Chinese
population would have facilitated the rapid appearance and spread of useful
innovations, including those at the purely biological level.33
It is
important to recognize that although good business ability was critical for the
long-term success of a line of Chinese peasants, the overall shaping
constraints differed considerably from those that might have affected a
mercantile caste such as the Ashkenazi Jews of Eastern Europe or the Parsis of
India. These latter groups occupied highly specialized economic niches in which
a keen head for figures or a ruthless business sense might have been all that
was required for personal success and prosperity. But in the world of rural
Chinese villages, even the wealthier elements usually spent the majority of the
lives in backbreaking labor, working alongside their families and their hired
men in the fields and rice paddies. Successful peasants might benefit from a
good intellect, but they also required the propensity for hard manual toil, determination,
diligence, and even such purely physical traits as resistance to injury and
efficiency in food digestion. Given such multiple selective pressures and
constraints, we would expect the shift in the prevalence of any single one of
these traits to be far slower than if it alone determined success, and the many
centuries of steady Chinese selection across the world’s largest population
would have been required to produce any substantial result.34
The impact
of such strong selective forces obviously manifests at multiple levels, with
cultural software being far more flexible and responsive than any gradual
shifts in innate tendencies, and distinguishing between evidence of these two
mechanisms is hardly a trivial task. But it seems quite unlikely that the
second, deeper sort of biological human change would not have occurred during a
thousand years or more of these relentlessly shaping pressures, and simply to
ignore or dismiss such an important possibility is unreasonable. Yet that seems
to have been the dominant strain of Western intellectual belief for the last
two or three generations.
Sometimes
the best means of recognizing one’s ideological blinders is to consider
seriously the ideas and perspectives of alien minds that lack them, and in the
case of Western society these happen to include most of our greatest
intellectual figures from 80 or 90 years ago, now suddenly restored to
availability by the magic of the Internet. Admittedly, in some respects these
individuals were naïve in their thinking or treated various ideas in crude
fashion, but in many more cases their analyses were remarkably acute and
scientifically insightful, often functioning as an invaluable corrective to the
assumed truths of the present. And in certain matters, notably predicting the
economic trajectory of the world’s largest country, they seem to have
anticipated developments that almost none of their successors of the past 50
years ever imagined. This should certainly give us pause.
Consider
also the ironic case of Bruce Lahn, a brilliant Chinese-born genetics
researcher at the University of Chicago. In an interview a few years ago, he
casually mentioned his speculation that the socially conformist tendencies of
most Chinese people might be due to the fact that for the past 2,000 years the
Chinese government had regularly eliminated its more rebellious subjects, a
suggestion that would surely be regarded as totally obvious and innocuous
everywhere in the world except in the West of the past half century or so. Not
long before that interview, Lahn had achieved great scientific acclaim for his
breakthrough discoveries on the possible genetic origins of human civilization,
but this research eventually provoked such heated controversy that he was
dissuaded from continuing it.35
Yet
although Chinese researchers living in America willingly conform to American
ideological restrictions, this is not the case with Chinese researchers in
China itself, and it is hardly surprising that BGI—the Beijing Genomics
Institute—has become the recognized world leader in cutting-edge human genetics
research. This is despite the billions spent by its American counterparts,
which must operate within a much more circumscribed framework of acceptable
ideas.
During the
Cold War, the enormous governmental investments of the Soviet regime in many
fields produced nothing, since they were based on a model of reality that was
both unquestionable and also false. The growing divergence between that
ideological model and the real world eventually doomed the USSR, whose vast and
permanent bulk blew away in a sudden gust of wind two decades ago. American
leaders should take care that they do not stubbornly adhere to scientifically
false doctrines that will lead our own country to risk a similar fate.
No comments:
Post a Comment