BY DARON ACEMOGLU , JAMES ROBINSON
Our recent book, Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty, received
the harshest reviews from those who see geography and culture as the root
causes of poverty, and enlightened leaders -- or even more enlightened outside
donors and organizations -- as the keys to economic development. Perhaps
unsurprisingly, given his dedication to international aid, billionaire
foundation chief Bill Gates falls into this category: His Feb. 26 review of our book
was particularly uncharitable. Unfortunately, however, it was also dead wrong
on many counts.
Gates's review
is disappointing, but not just because he disagrees with us. As academics, we
expect that. Research is all about arguing and contradicting, finding new
pieces of evidence, developing new concepts and perspectives, and getting
closer to the truth. Alas, Gates fails in this endeavor. His inability to
understand even the most rudimentary parts of our thesis means that his review
fails to invite constructive argument. Nonetheless, we feel compelled to
respond because of the undue attention the review has generated.
To start with,
Gates makes some pretty baffling statements about our book, such as his
assertion that "important terms aren't really defined." Actually, all
of the major concepts we use in the book are defined;
one just needs to read the book. Other assertions demonstrate not only that
Gates is unfamiliar with the academic literature, which is understandable, but
that he actually did not bother to consult the bibliographic essay and the
references at the end. He writes, "The authors ... attribute the decline
of Venice to a reduction in the inclusiveness of its institutions. The fact is,
Venice declined because competition came along ... Even if Venice had managed
to preserve the inclusiveness of their institutions, it would not have made up
for their loss of the spice trade."
This is just bad
history. Venice didn't decline because of the loss of the spice trade. If that
were the case, the decline should have started at the very end of the 15th
century. But the decline was already well underway by the middle of the 14th
century. More generally, research by Diego
Puga and Daniel Trefler shows that Venice's fortunes had nothing to do with
competition or the spice trade.
Likewise, Gates
seems to think that the Maya declined because of the "weather."
Though there is certainly scholarly dispute over why Maya civilization decayed,
to our knowledge no reputable scholar argues that it was due to the weather.
Instead, most scholars emphasize the role of inter-city warfare and the
collapse of Mayan political institutions. Nor does the book, as Gates would
have it, "overlook the incredible period of growth and innovation in China
between 800 and 1400." We discuss that period, and explain why it didn't
translate into sustained economic growth (see Chapter 8, in particular, pp.
231-234).
Gates also says
at one point that our book "refers to me in a positive light." Sorry,
we do no such thing. We point out that Gates, just like Mexican telecom mogul
Carlos Slim, would have loved to form a monopoly. He tried and failed. What our
book shows in a positive light are the U.S. institutions, such the Department
of Justice, that stopped Gates and Microsoft from cornering the market. We say,
"sadly there are few heroes in this book." Bill Gates was not one of
them.
On a related
note, Gates writes that that our book is "quite unfair to Slim."
Mexico, he contends, is "much better off with Slim's contribution in
running businesses well than it would be without him." But once again,
this reveals a lack of understanding of our main thesis, which isn't that
Carlos Slim is evil and the root cause of Mexico's problems. We argue that
ambitious entrepreneurs like Gates or Slim will do good for society if
inclusive institutions constrain them, and that they will mostly serve their
own interests otherwise. So the right counterfactual to Slim isn't no Slim, but
a Mexico in which people like Slim (and hundreds of other talented would-be
entrepreneurs who never got the opportunity to flourish because of the
country's poor education system or because of its terrible competition laws)
operate within the context of inclusive economic institutions and therefore
enrich their society to a much greater extent.
For the record,
however, before cheerleading Slim, Gates might want to read the OECD's 2012
report on telecommunications policy and regulation in
Mexico, which estimates the social costs of Slim's monopoly at U.S. $129
billion and counting. (The latest Forbes list of
the world's richest people puts Slim's net worth at U.S. $79 billion). So in
what way is Mexico better off exactly?
Gates also
complains in his review that we "ridicule modernization theory." We
don't. We try to articulate an alternative theory of extractive growth -- which
takes place under extractive, authoritarian political institutions -- where
countries grow because their leadership controlling these extractive
institutions feels secure and able to control and benefit from the growth
process. This occupies a large part of our book because it is a central feature
of economic and political development over the last several thousand years. Our
theory suggests why extractive growth doesn't automatically lead to more
inclusive institutions: Growth is made possible, at least in most cases, by the
leaders and dominant elites' belief in their relative security.
Gates is right
that there are examples like South Korea (which we discussed in the book) that
have transitioned to more inclusive institutions following a period of extractive
growth. But South Korea's transition to democracy in the 1980s was in no way
automatic. It came about as a result of protests by students and workers
against the military regime, and only after the repression by the military
failed to quell the unrest. More importantly, as a cursory look at our
bibliographic essay would have shown, our dismissal of modernization theory
isn't based on a few case studies or a gut feeling, but on careful econometric
evidence. See, for example, our papers titled "Income and Democracy" and
"Re-evaluating the Modernization Hypothesis, both jointly authored with
Simon Johnson and Pierre Yared.
At another point
in his review, Gates contends that economic growth is "strongly correlated
with embracing capitalistic economics." Yet it is far from clear what he
means by "capitalistic economics." Were Egypt's economic institutions
during the presidency of Hosni Mubarak -- after he liberalized the economy and
reduced the role of the state -- capitalistic? Most people refer to this as
"crony capitalism," but perhaps this is all part of capitalist
economics? Or consider the long dictatorship of Porfirio Diaz in Mexico in the
19th century, which eradicated many of the remaining restrictions of the
Spanish colonial system, established an economy based on private enterprise
(especially of his cronies), and "freed" markets (including the
creation of the market for coerced labor). Was that capitalistic? What about South
Africa under apartheid, based on private enterprise by whites, but
disempowering and exploiting the majority blacks? Perhaps Gates himself should
have more carefully defined his terms.
The concept of
capitalism doesn't feature in our book for good reason. It muddies the waters.
Our point, by which we stand strongly, is that what distinguishes societies
isn't whether they are centrally planned or capitalist, but whether they are
extractive or inclusive. Though centrally planned economies are by their nature
extractive, so are many "capitalist" economies.
Finally, Gates
takes issue with our supposedly "huge attack on foreign aid," citing
in particular our "misleading" claims about Afghanistan. But again,
he would have benefited from looking at the bibliography. The finding that
about 10 percent of foreign aid goes to intended recipients isn't from
Afghanistan, as he seems to think, but from Uganda, which was not a war zone
but a peaceful country at the time of the 2004 study we cite.
More importantly, there is now considerable evidence showing that foreign aid
in the postwar era has had little positive impact on economic development,
which Gates chooses to ignore (see, for example, William Easterly's White Man's Burden). Denying this
is really putting your head in the sand.
But even sadder
is the fact that we don't even argue against foreign aid. What we argue in the
book is that aid -- the little of it that reaches its target -- does a lot of
good for poor people. But it is not the solution to the real problems of
development. Instead of endlessly asserting empirically untenable positions, we
all need to move on and find more constructive ways to engage with poor
countries. Foreign aid should certainly be part -- but not all -- of this
engagement.
Gates does
correctly point out that much is missing from the framework in our book. Even
if underdevelopment isn't just a problem of bad leadership, and even if its
solution won't come from enlightened leaders, a more complete framework should
indeed integrate the behavior of leaders that play an important role in state
building, organizing collective action, and articulating visions for social
change. Examples of such leaders include Tunisia's Habib Bourguiba and
Singapore's Lee Kuan Yew, both of whom undoubtedly influenced the course of
their country's development. But we chose to emphasize institutions in our book
because for leadership to have a lasting impact, it must become
institutionalized via inclusive political institutions. After several decades
of promoting education and developing a Tunisian national identity, for
example, Bourguiba, who ran Tunisia as a dictator, was elbowed out of power by
a very different sort of strongman, Zine El Abidine Ben Ali, who was far more
interested in using his power to loot the country's resources. But Gates
doesn't seem to be interested in such subtleties, preferring instead to
criticize every aspect of Why Nations Fail.
Some say that
all publicity is good publicity, and we should be thrilled to have Bill Gates
review our book. Publicity is nice. But we spent more than 15 years
researching, writing, and thinking about these topics, and we would be thrilled
if the reviewers actually read and understood the book in the first place. Then
we could have a constructive debate about the root causes of poverty in the
world.
No comments:
Post a Comment