Better Still, Free Banking
The “Cyprus deal” as it has been widely
referred to in the media may mark the next to last act in the the slow motion
collapse of fractional-reserve banking that began with the implosion of the
savings-and-loan industry in the U.S. in the late 1980s.
This
trend continued with the currency crises in Russia, Mexico, East Asia, and
Argentina in the 1990s in which fractional-reserve banking played a decisive
role. The unraveling of fractional-reserve banking became visible even to the
average depositor during the financial meltdown of 2008 that ignited bank runs
on some of the largest and most venerable financial institutions in the world.
The final collapse was only averted by the multi-trillion
dollar bailout of U.S. and foreign banks by the Federal Reserve.
Even
more than the unprecedented financial crisis of 2008, however, recent events in
Cyprus may have struck the mortal blow to fractional-reserve banking. For
fractional-reserve banking can only exist for as long as the depositors have
complete confidence that regardless of the financial woes that befall the bank
entrusted with their “deposits,” they will always be
able to withdraw them on demand at par in currency, the ultimate cash of any
banking system.
Ever
since World War Two governmental deposit insurance, backed up by the
money-creating powers of the central bank, was seen as the unshakable guarantee
that warranted such confidence. In effect, fractional-reserve banking was
perceived as 100-percent banking by depositors, who acted as if their money was
always “in the bank” thanks to the ability of central banks to conjure up money
out of thin air (or in cyberspace).
Perversely
the various crises involving fractional-reserve banking that struck time and
again since the late 1980s only reinforced this belief among depositors,
because troubled banks and thrift institutions were always bailed out with
alacrity—especially the largest and least stable. Thus arose the
“too-big-to-fail doctrine.” Under this doctrine, uninsured bank depositors and
bondholders were generally made whole when large banks failed, because it was
widely understood that the confidence in the entire banking system was a frail
and evanescent thing that would break and completely dissipate as a result of
the failure of even a single large institution.
Getting
back to the Cyprus deal, admittedly it is hardly ideal from a free-market point
of view. The solution in accord with free markets would not involve restricting
deposit withdrawals, imposing fascistic capital controls on domestic residents
and foreign investors, and dragooning taxpayers in the rest of the Eurozone
into contributing to the bailout to the tune of 10 billion euros.
Nonetheless,
the deal does convey a salutary message to bank depositors and creditors the
world over. It does so by forcing previously untouchable senior bondholders and
uninsured depositors in the Cypriot banks to bear part of the cost of the
bailout. The bondholders of the two largest banks will be wiped out and it is reported that large depositors (i.e., those holding
uninsured accounts exceeding 100,000 euros) at the Laiki Bank may also be
completely wiped out, losing up to 4.2 billion euros, while large depositors at
the Bank of Cyprus will lose between 30 and 60 percent of their deposits. Small
depositors in both banks, who hold insured accounts of up to 100,000 euros,
would retain the full value of their deposits.
The
happy result will be that depositors, both insured and uninsured, in Europe and
throughout the world will become much more cautious or even suspicious in
dealing with fractional-reserve banks. They will be poised to grab their money
and run at the slightest sign or rumor of instability. This will induce banks
to radically alter the sources of the funds they raise to finance loans and
investments, moving away from deposit and toward equity and bond financing. As was
reported Tuesday, March 26, this is already expected by many analysts:
One
potential spillover from the March 26 agreement is the knock-on effects for
bank funding, analysts said. Banks typically fund themselves with some combination
of deposits, equity, senior and subordinate notes and covered bonds, which are
backed by a pool of high-quality assets that stay on the lender’s balance sheet.
The
consequences of the Cyprus bailout could be that banks will be more likely to
use contingent convertible bonds—known as CoCos—to raise money as their ability
to encumber assets by issuing covered bonds reaches regulatory limits, said
Chris Bowie at Ignis Asset Management Ltd. in London.
“We’d
expect to see some deposit flight and a shift in funding towards a combination
of covered bonds, real equity and quasi-equity,” said Bowie, who is head of
credit portfolio management at Ignis, which oversees about $110 billion.
If this
indeed occurs it will be a significant move toward a free-market financial
system in which the radical mismatching of the maturities of assets and
liabilities in the case of demand deposits is eliminated once and for all. A
few more banking crises in the Eurozone—especially one in which insured
depositors are made to participate in the so-called “bail-in”—will likely cause
the faith in government deposit insurance to completely evaporate and with it
confidence in the fractional-reserve banking system.
There
may then naturally arise on the market a system in which equity, bonds, and
genuine time deposits that cannot be redeemed before maturity become the
exclusive sources of finance for bank loans and investments. Demand deposits,
whether checkable or not, would be segregated in actual deposit banks which
maintain 100-percent reserves and provide a range of payments systems from ATMs
to debit cards.
While
this conjecture may be overly optimistic, we are certainly a good deal closer
to such an outcome today than we were before the “Cyprus deal” was struck. Of
course we would be closer still if there were no bailout and the full brunt of
the bank failures were borne solely by the creditors and depositors of the
failed banks rather than partly by taxpayers. The latter solution would have
completely and definitively exposed the true nature of fractional-reserve
banking for all to see.
No comments:
Post a Comment