The imperial tree falls not because the challenges are too great but because the core of the tree has been weakened by the gradual loss of surplus, purpose, institutional effectiveness, intellectual vigor and productive investment.
by Charles Hugh-Smith
Comparing
the American Empire with the Roman Empire in its terminal decline is a popular
intellectual parlor game. The comparison is inexact on a number of fronts, starting with the
nature of empire: Rome ruled a territorial empire, while the U.S. is a hegemony
that doesn't need to hold territory (other than key overseas military bases);
its dominance is based on the global projection of hard and soft power,
diplomacy, finance and the monetary regime of the reserve currency.
Despite
the apparent difference, the two empires share the key characteristic of all
enduring empires: they extract the cost of maintaining the empire from client states
and/or allies.
The
mechanisms differ, but the results are the same: the empire's cost is
distributed to those who benefit from its secure trade routes.
Two of
the key characteristics of an empire in terminal decline are complacency and
intellectual sclerosis, what I have termed a failure of imagination.
Michael
Grant described these causes of decline in his excellent account The Fall of the Roman Empire, a short book I have been recommending
since 2009:
There was no room at all, in these ways of thinking, for the novel, apocalyptic situation which had now arisen, a situation which needed solutions as radical as itself. (The Status Quo) attitude is a complacent acceptance of things as they are, without a single new idea.
This acceptance was accompanied by greatly excessive optimism about the present and future. Even when the end was only sixty years away, and the Empire was already crumbling fast, Rutilius continued to address the spirit of Rome with the same supreme assurance.
This blind adherence to the ideas of the past ranks high among the principal causes of the downfall of Rome. If you were sufficiently lulled by these traditional fictions, there was no call to take any practical first-aid measures at all.
In other words, if our idea of intellectual rigor and honesty is Paul
Krugman dancing around the Neo-Keynesian Cargo Cult campfire waving dead
chickens and mumbling nonsensical claims of grand success, we are well and
truly doomed.
The chapter titles of the book give a precis of the other causes Grant
identifies:
The Gulfs Between the Classes
The Credibility Gap
The Partnerships That Failed
The Groups That Opted Out
The Undermining of Effort
I recently
read a lengthier book by Adrian Goldsworthy titled How Rome Fell: Death of a Superpower. In Goldsworthy's view, a key driver
of decline was the constant political struggle for power drained resources away
from protecting the Imperial borders from barbarian incursions and addressing
the long-term problems facing the Empire.
Such
conflicts for the Imperial throne often led to outright civil war, with
factions of the Roman army meeting on the field of battle.
In
other words, Rome didn't fall so much as erode away, its many strengths
squandered on in-fighting, mismanagement and personal aggrandizement/corruption.
More
telling for the present is Goldsworthy's identification of expansive, sclerotic
bureaucracies that lost sight of their purpose. The top leadership abandoned the
pursuit of the common good for personal gain, wealth and power. This rot at the
top soon spread down the chain of command to infect and corrupt the entire
institutional culture.
As the
empire shrank and lost tax revenues, the Imperial bureaucracies continued
growing, much as parasites attach themselves to a weakened host.
Individual
contributions and institutional success are both difficult to measure in large
bureaucracies, and it is tempting to define success by easily achieved metrics
that reflect positively on individual contributions and the institutional
management.
As the
organization loses focus on its original purpose, the core purpose of the
institution is given lip service but is replaced with facsimiles of managerial
effectiveness, bureaucratic infighting over resources and the targeting of
easily gamed metrics as substitutes for actual success.
People
who have no skin in the game behave quite differently from those who face
consequences. This disconnection of risk from consequence is called moral
hazard.
Bureaucracies
tend to institutionalize moral hazard: those managing the institution’s
departments rarely suffer any personal consequence when the institution fails
to perform its function. Funds are placed at risk, but the individuals making
the bets with the institution’s money suffer no losses should their policies
result in failure.
By
breaking the institutional purpose into small pieces whose success is measured
by easily gamed targets, the institution can be failing its primary function
even as every department reports continued success in meeting its goals.
Repeated failure and loss of focus erode the institution even as those in
charge advance up the administrative ladder.
In the
final years of the Empire, in the 5th century A.D., this institutional failure
led to the absurdity of detailed descriptions of army units being distributed
within the Imperial bureaucracy, while the actual units themselves--the troops,
the officers and the equipment--had ceased to exist. In some cases, it appears
bureaucrats and officers collected pay for supplying and commanding completely
phantom legions.
The
disconnect between the failure to fulfill the institution’s original function
and the leadership’s rise feeds cynicism in the institution’s employees and
erodes their purpose and initiative. Soon the institutional culture is one of
self-aggrandizement, gaming of departmental targets, protection of budgets and
a collapse of the work ethic to the minimum level needed to avoid dismissal.
Personal responsibility for institutional failure is lost.
Does
this describe the vast state fiefdoms and state-protected cartels of America's
military-industrial complex, sickcare and the education industry? I think the
answer is self-evident: yes. While there are still hard-working, competent people within these
sprawling empires of moral hazard, these few are not enough to wring long-term
success from negligence, friction and incompetence. All they can do is stave
off implosion for a time.
There
are many other causes for Rome's decline, including epidemics of plague,
military over-reach, chronic deficits, debasement of the currency, a parasitic
Elite that was immune to what was left of the rule of law, weak leadership, and
rising dependence on the Central State for bread and circuses.
America
is not Rome, just as the immensely successful Tang Empire in China (700-900
A.D.) was neither Rome nor America. These dissimilarities should not blind us
to the underlying dynamics in the decline and fall of all great powers, which
can be summarized as the slow erosion of shared purpose, surplus and
the productive investment of that surplus.
When a
storm arises -- a conflict with neighboring powers, an outbreak of plague, a
disastrous drought--the imperial tree falls, not because the challenge was too
great but because the core of the tree had been weakened by the gradual loss of
surplus, purpose, institutional effectiveness, intellectual vigor and
productive investment.
No comments:
Post a Comment