For the past 10 years, France has had one of the highest levels of public spending in the world
I'VE made the
point before - I have a fraught relationship with France. What's not to love
about boeuf bourguignon, the Riviera and Sancerre white wine? And how good are
tarte tatin, the Musee D'Orsay and Carcasonne? (OK, Carcasonne is a bit tacky
these days.)
But when it comes
to running an economy, let's face it, the French have no bleedin' idea.
Let me pose this
question: when did the French government last run a budget surplus? Here's a
hint: Wyatt Roy's parents were still at school and probably didn't know each
other. The answer is 1974-75.
But, boy, do they
know how to run budget deficits, as the chart shows. Deficits in excess of 3
per cent of GDP are common. More recently, we have seen budget deficits above 7
per cent of GDP. The government sector in France accounts for more than half of
total output and government debt is running at 90 per cent of GDP.
If you are a
fully-signed up member of the Keynesian school of thought, the expectation is
that, with all that continuous pump-priming, the French economy should be going
gang busters. But, alas, the opposite is the case.
Unemployment in
France is 10.6 per cent and rising. Youth unemployment is just over 25 per
cent. The French economy is flat-lining, having been in and out of recession
for the past four years.
One of the strange
features of the French economy is that the country has produced world-class
companies, including L'Oreal, Michelin, LVMH, Total, AXA and Alcatel-Lucent.
Once upon a time, French banks were admired - they were specialists in the
provision of trade credit, for instance - but their reputation and fortunes
have taken quite a battering in recent times.
But the short
explanation for France's dreadful overall economic performance is the
combination of an excessively large government sector, ill-directed spending,
badly designed taxes and stifling regulations, particularly affecting the
labour market. The
current Labour Code runs to more than 3000 pages!
If you think I am
alone in this assessment, consider some recent comments from Christian Noyer,
the governor of Banque de France, the country's central bank. (I think I might
have developed a bit of a crush on him, even though he is French.)
Writing recently,
Noyer argued that: "The underlying objective is growth. Not just a
temporary spurt, sustained artificially by public spending, but strong and lasting
growth that creates jobs and is based on the development of modern and
competitive production capacity. This kind of growth cannot just be summoned
up. It requires a profound change in public policy." He's my kind of man.
"For the past
10 years, France has had one of the highest levels of public spending in the
world. Over a certain threshold, which our country has probably crossed, any
increase in public spending and debt has extremely negative effects on
confidence. For this reason, trying to stimulate growth through a spending
binge is bound to be counterproductive. Businesses and households, anticipating
higher future taxes to pay for the binge, will cut back, offsetting any boost
from deficit spending." The only quibble I have is the inclusion of the
adverb "probably".
On France's
inflexible labour market, Noyer states that France "is one of the biggest
spenders on employment policies in the developed world, but it still has one of
the highest levels of unemployment".
He then poses this
question: "Do these subsidies not serve to offset market rigidities that
could in fact be addressed directly at a lower cost and with more effective
results?" He makes specific mention of the capacity of German firms to
reduce working hours when economic conditions soften which contrasts with the
restrictions that apply in France.
Acknowledging the
changing nature of the labour market, Noyer argues that "public policies
are often overly concerned with preserving the jobs of the past, at times to
the detriment of future job creation. Today's jobs are not the same as those of
yesterday and, likewise, those of tomorrow will be different from the jobs that
exist today".
The Australian
government might care to take note.
Just to prove that
Noyer is not a lone voice on this issue, consider this 2009 quote from
Christine Lagarde, when she was France's finance minister, but is now chief of
the International Monetary Fund. "Instead of thinking about their work,
(French) people think about their weekends, organising, planning and
engineering time off. If you say to a French person, 'Would you like to be an
entrepreneur?' all they do is run scared."
So what are the
features of the rigidities that afflict the operation of the French labour
market? Extremely high minimum wages, restrictions on the ability of firms to
reduce the number of workers, excessive redundancy payments, and the list goes
on.
There have been a
number of high-profile cases that illustrate the lunacy of French labour laws.
Take the example of the Goodyear's loss-making tyre factory in Amiens. Earlier
in the year, the company announced it would be shutting the plant and cutting
its workforce in France because of "industrial disputes and plunging car
demand in Europe".
A potential sale
of the plant to US company Titan International was on the table until the
chairman of the company visited the plant: "I have visited the factory
several times. The French workforce gets paid high wages but works for only
three hours. They get one hour for breaks and lunch, talk for three hours and
work for three. I told the French union workers this to their faces. They told
me that that's the French way!"
The trouble is
that the French way does not provide a conducive environment for investment and
risk-taking. Without some radical changes to the Labour Code - there have been
some minor modifications - and other major changes involving a smaller
government sector, the outlook for the French economy is grim.
No comments:
Post a Comment