Most of the modern discussion on
immigration policy is directed to the question of which aliens who enter into
the United States should be allowed a path to citizenship and why. In
dealing with that topic, Gary Becker and Edward Lazear have powerfully argued that a market
system is the best way to attract “people with skills and vision” into the
United States. That program is correct as far as it goes. But in a sense it
does not go far enough. Immigration policy cannot concern itself only
with the long and complex progression from entry to citizenship. It must
also deal with another reality of the modern integrated global economy, namely,
the way in which the United States—and for that matter other nations—admit
individuals on short-term work visas.
These visas are of immense importance
especially at the higher echelons of the workforce, for nothing is more common
today than for key employees in global firms to do short-term tours of duty in
the United States, even when they have no intention to seek permanent residence
or U.S. citizenship. In two important ways, these cases present far fewer
problems than do foreign entrants into the United States in search of permanent
status. Often these business entrants come with substantial income and
without families, and hence do not put the kinds of pressure on domestic social
support systems than do entrants with large families and limited levels of
support. In addition, since these workers do not aspire to citizenship, they
will not obtain the right to vote, which adds an important political dimension
to their entry into this country.
Given these two features, it is proper to
think of these short-term visitors as labor inputs in voluntary markets with no
systematic negative externalities. At this point, as I have argued here the proper treatment of their
participation in these labor markets should follow the same approach that
ideally applies to the movement of goods in international markets: free and
open markets, which applies to entry and exit across national boundary
lines. The key principle of international trade in either goods or
services is, or at least should be, that two or more sovereigns so organize
their affairs that all transactions in goods and services follow the same
competitive principles that govern a well-functioning domestic market.
Indeed one great advantage of the United States is that its constitutional
jurisprudence by and large prohibits any state in the union from imposing
barriers to entry and exit of either labor or goods that are not narrowly
justified by the need to protect against such clear perils as contaminated
goods. The competition that takes place, say, between Michigan and Tennessee in
labor markets operates as a powerful force for deregulation in domestic
markets, which in the end helped erode the strong pro-union structure in
Michigan. When faced with competition from right-to-work states, Michigan
recently felt compelled to pass a right-to-work law over fierce union opposition to
prevent the further loss of business to low-cost labor states. Note that
under the federalist system, there is no quota on the number of workers that
can move from state to state, and no requirement that they gain any certificate
that proves that they are competent to work.
There are reasons why this federal will
not work in the same way in international markets—chiefly because the number of
potential foreigners who might wish to enter could overwhelm the overall system
of social supports. That influx cannot happen between states within a single
nation that imposes some limits on immigration from overseas. But if
excessive entry turns out to be a problem, the correct response is to set up a
number of slots for admission and then allow an open bidding system for slots
of some specific duration. Either domestic firms or foreign immigrants
could bid for the slots (which need not be of uniform duration), and the sole
obligation on the winners is to register the workers who have entered under the
program so that they can be asked to leave when their appointed time within the
country is over.
The current system of H-1B visas in the United States falls far short
of that ideal. Far from having that characteristic, the temporary visa
program in the United States is shot through with protectionist shortcomings
that go a long way to vitiate the gains that the United States gets from this
visa program. The program stands condemned in its own words, when it sets
forth “certain prerequisites for employers wishing to employ H-1B workers.” Thus
the required file a Labor Condition Application contains at a minimum these
indefensible provisions:
· Pay the nonimmigrant workers at least the local prevailing wage or the employer’s actual wage, whichever is higher; pay for non-productive time in certain circumstances; and offer benefits on the same basis as for U.S. workers;
· Provide working conditions for H-1B, H-1B1, or E-3 workers that will not adversely affect the working conditions of workers similarly employed;
· Not employ an H-1B, H-1B1, or E-3 worker at a location where a strike or lockout in the occupational classification is occurring, and notify ETA of any future strike or lockout; and
· On or within 30 days before the date the LCA is filed with ETA, provide notice of the employer’s intent to hire H-1B, H-1B1, or E-3 workers. The employer must provide this notice to the bargaining representative of workers in the occupation in which the H-1B, H-1B1, or E-3 worker will be employed. If there is no bargaining representative, the employer must post such notices in conspicuous locations at the intended place(s) of employment, or provide them electronically.
The obvious intention and key defect in
the system is that it imposes an elaborate set of requirements intended to
protect the wages now paid to American professionals from direct competition by
foreign labor. It seems quite clear that no domestic market works well
when the legal system imposes barriers to domestic competition. The same is
true when foreign competition is on the table. The great vice of the
system is that it assumes that the loss in wages to some direct competitors
should be treated as if it were a social loss, when in fact the opposite is
true.
The reason why these losses are termed
“pecuniary externalities” in ordinary parlance is that there is a negative correlation
between the position of the disappointed competitor and overall social
welfare. Looking at disappointed competitors ignores the gains to others
individuals, both domestic and foreign from the increased competition in given
market sectors. Those gains are found in the increased opportunities that
these new entrants give to other workers, which surely happens when the new
entrant establishes or expands a business. And it ignores the systematic
gains to consumers from the combination of lower prices and superior
services. Just that same set of relationships emerges in the
international market, which means that it is both costly and dangerous to
require firms to present elaborate case-by-case explanations as to why they
should be allowed to continue to hire a given worker for a given
position. This nation could cut administrative costs, eliminate political
intrigue, and improve overall productivity if it stripped out any and all
government oversight with respect to these temporary visas. The key task
of the government is to pick the number and length of these visas and then get
out of they way. The fine-tuning of labor markets is a consistent loser
domestically. It works no better in dealing with temporary workers from
outside the United States.
No comments:
Post a Comment