The public sees trade as a zero sum game between Us and Them
Has the
intellectual debate about free trade been won? The close-to-consensus answer
among several scholars discussing that question at Cato last week is “yes.” The
better answer is “wrong question.” After all, how much does it really matter
that free traders have won the intellectual debate when, in practice, trade
policy is distinctly anti-intellectual and free trade is the rare exception,
not the rule, around the world?
Consider the
just-launched Transatlantic Trade
and Investment Partnership negotiations. If the free
trade consensus were meaningful outside the ivory tower, these negotiations
would not take place. At the heart of the talks rests the fallacy that protectionism
is an asset to be dispensed with only if reciprocated, in roughly equal
measure, by “negotiators” on the other side of the table. But if free trade
were the rule, trade policy would have a purely domestic orientation and U.S.
barriers would be removed without any need for negotiation because they would
be recognized for what they are: taxes on consumers and businesses. It really
is that simple.
But the TTIP is
shaping up to be the mother of all negotiations: an interminable feast of
mercantilist horse-trading, self-serving press conferences, and ever-premature,
congratulatory pronouncements all intended to aggrandize negotiators and
politicians who thirst to be seen doing something to restore economic hope
without having to shake their respective vested interests from their protected
perches. It’s all quite nauseating, really, but at least it serves to remind us
that free trade is the rare exception, and when all else fails…
Granted, U.S.
tariffs are relatively low on average, most quotas have gone away, and most
other countries have reduced barriers to trade over the past half century,
which has contributed in no small part to improvements in per capita income and
quality of life around the world. Why that cause and effect hasn’t reinforced
the theory enough to drive a stake through the heart of protectionism is the
better question.
In the United
States, instead of free trade, we have protectionism in its many guises,
including: “Buy American” rules for government procurement; heavily protected
services industries; apparently inextinguishable farm subsidies; sugar quotas;
green-energy subsidies; industrial policy; the Export-Import bank; antidumping
duties; regulatory protectionism masquerading as public health and safety
regulations, and; the protectionism euphemistically embedded in so-called free
trade agreements in the forms of rules of origin, local content requirements,
intellectual property and investment protections, enforceable labor and
environmental standards, and special carve-outs that immunize products – even
industries – from international competition. In fact, the entire enterprise of
trade negotiations is a paean to protectionism, conducted with the utmost care
to avoid unsettling, without recompense, the special privileges of the status
quo.
How has an
intellectual consensus for free trade coexisted with these numerous and
metastasizing affronts to it? Protectionism slipped the noose, that’s how.
Thanks to – among
many others – Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Jacob Viner, Milton Friedman, Jagdish
Bhagwati, and even the pundit once known as economist Paul Krugman,
protectionism fell into disrepute. Gone are the days when routine requests for
tariffs and other trade barriers were honored by Congress on the strength of
the argument that it would be good for domestic industry’s bottom line, and
thus members’ reelection prospects. Seeking protection became unsavory – a
bald-faced effort to plunder.
So protectionism
needed a makeover, which it found by drawing sustenance from the argument that
it is a legitimate response to “unfair” or otherwise “objectionable” practices
abroad. The popular appeal of concepts like fairness and level playing fields
made protectionism less unpalatable, which opened the door to ever-expanding
definitions of “unfair” and “contingent protectionism.” Today, protectionism is
omnipresent and the well of rationalizations intended to de-stigmatize it is
seemingly bottomless.
The presumption of
foreign cheating and unfairness, reinforced by the fallacy that the United
States is the world’s most open economy, undergirds a perverse sense of
entitlement to protectionism among Americans – as though that protection
somehow benefits them instead of the U.S. companies that are now more free to
raise prices and limit offerings at their individual expenses. At the heart of
this mess is the utterly mistaken view that trade is a contest between “Us” and
“Them,” between our producers and their producers. More than anything else,
this particular misconception explains the divide between economists and the
general public over the question of free trade. The public sees trade as a zero
sum game between Us and Them, where exports are Team USA’s points, imports are
the foreign team’s points, and trade restrictions are not taxes, but a strong
defense.
By entrenching
this kind of thinking, trade negotiations, such as the TTIP, do a disservice to
the truth. Too many Americans are inclined to don their rally caps in support
of Team USA’s performance in the Great Trade Negotiations of 2013, as though it
were their own personal interests – and not the interests of U.S. industries
that would swiftly deny them better choices and better prices – that U.S.
negotiators have at heart and in mind. Perhaps, the next time these fans find
themselves on a delayed flight, sandwiched between sweaty passengers in the
stuffy cabin of an aged aircraft on a crowded tarmac because of some checklist
oversight of an airline employee, they might consider how Team USA’s
negotiators in the TTIP adamantly oppose competition from foreign carriers
between U.S cities because that’s what the domestic carriers and their unions
want. Free trade – not the Chamber of Commerce’s or the AFL-CIO’s or the
official U.S. negotiating agenda – is what Americans should support.
Still, the trade
policy industrial complex is in general conformity over the crusty premise that
reciprocity-based trade negotiations are the right way to liberalize trade.
Despite the enormous benefits and the fundamental fairness of allowing people
their freedom to transact how and with whom they please, we have conceded
without compelling reason to a system of managed trade that aims, in theory, to
balance the pro-export advocacy of business interests and the anti-import
proclivities of labor and other anti-corporate NGOs, and in the process made
politicians and bureaucrats the gatekeepers. Left hanging out to dry in this
formulation are U.S. consumers, import-consuming industries, the better
mousetraps and better opportunities that would emerge and the dignity of having
real freedom to engage in commerce with whomever we choose on terms
not influenced by political interference.
Whether there is
an intellectual consensus for free trade seems to be of secondary importance.
Unless and until free traders do a better job of marketing the truth, we will
be stuck with the trade policy that we have, which is hard to distinguish from
corporate welfare and crony capitalism. Business associations, unions
and other interests line up at policymakers’ doors seeking “permission to” or
“exclusion from,” which reinforces
the terrible idea that politicians should guard the henhouse, deciding who
benefits, who loses, and at what costs.
This
aggrandizement of politics makes us poorer. Instead of committing resources to
productive endeavors like production and R&D, too many companies are
compelled to divert resources to their government affairs offices because the
return on lobbying turns out to be more profitable. And, in the process, Washington grows more
glorious still.
No comments:
Post a Comment