Europe’s Youth
Unemployment Non-Problem
European
policymakers have decided that they must be seen to be “doing something” about youth
unemployment. A special summit of Europe’s heads of state has been called, and
a “Youth Employment Initiative,” proposed at
the EU Council of Ministers’ meeting in February, aims to “reinforce and
accelerate” measures that were recommended in a “Youth Employment Package” in December
2012.
This activism
comes mainly in response to the latest alarming figures on youth unemployment
in southern Europe, with sky-high rates of joblessness widely regarded as
politically unacceptable. But there are several reasons to doubt that youth unemployment
is a discrete problem meriting special treatment. Indeed, official youth
unemployment statistics are misleading on two counts.
First, the data
refer to those from 15 to 24 years old. But this age group consists of two
sub-groups with very different characteristics. The “teenagers” (15-19 years
old) should mostly still be in school; if not, they are likely to be very low
skilled – and thus to have difficulty finding a full-time job even in good
times. Fortunately, this group is rather small (and has been declining in size
over time).
Unemployment among
those aged 20-24 should be more troubling. Members of this cohort who are
seeking full-time employment have typically completed upper secondary
education, but have decided not to pursue university education (or have
completed their university studies early).
Second, the data
on youth unemployment are based on active labor-market participants. But
labor-market participation averages just 10% among teenagers in Europe.
(Teenage activity rates come close to 50% only in countries like the
Netherlands and the United Kingdom, where having a part-time job while in
school is very common.)
Labor-market
experts thus consider the unemployment rate a potentially misleading indicator,
because a youth unemployment rate of 50% does not mean that half of the young
population is unemployed. That is why one should look at the unemployment ratio –
the percentage of the unemployed in the reference population – rather than at
the unemployment rate.
Indeed, this
indicator paints a somewhat less alarming picture than that created by the
headline youth-unemployment rate of more than 50% in Spain, or even the 62.5% rate recently reached in Greece. The
youth-unemployment rate in Greece does not mean that close to two-thirds of
young Greeks are unemployed. Only 9% of Greek teenagers are labor-market
participants; two-thirds of that number cannot find a job. The
unemployment ratio among teenagers in Greece is thus less than 6%. But this
figure is not reported widely because it is much less alarming.
Among those in the
20-24 age group, the difference between the reported unemployment rate and the
percentage of youth without a job and looking for one (the unemployment ratio)
is less stark. But, even among this age group, one finds that the unemployment
ratio is often about one-half of the widely reported unemployment rate.
Moreover, one must
ask how much youth unemployment contributes to total unemployment. Looking at
the problem this way reveals a completely different picture from the one
usually presented.
In those countries
where the problem makes the biggest headlines (the eurozone’s south, with
Greece and Spain supposedly the worst cases), youth unemployment accounts for
less than a quarter of overall unemployment. By contrast, youth unemployment
contributes relatively much more (about 40%) to overall unemployment in
countries like Sweden and the UK. One could argue that the latter two should
worry about their youth unemployment more than Spain or Greece should.
The fact that
youth unemployment is just a part of a larger problem leads to the real policy
question: Why should officials spend limited time, energy, and public funding
specifically on unemployed young people, rather than on all of the unemployed?
Does a teenager’s
unemployment represent a greater loss to society than that of a single mother
or an older worker, who might have been providing an entire family’s only
income? The loss of the value added produced by a teenager is probably much
lower.
In purely economic
terms, one could thus argue that youth unemployment (especially teenage
part-time unemployment) is much less important than unemployment among those
who are in their prime earning years. Moreover, young people have the option of
continuing their education, thus adding to future earnings power, whereas
continuing education is a much less viable alternative for their elders.
Europe has a general
macroeconomic problem, owing to demand factors that interact with a rigid labor
market, rather than a specific youth-unemployment problem. This implies that
there is no need for ad hoc measures for young people, which
merely risk overloading welfare systems with even more exemptions and special
rules.
No comments:
Post a Comment