Any Republican who voted for this bill and then claims to care about the debt or deficits should be laughed off the stage
By Michael D. Tanner
Whenever Republicans attempt to cut
spending for some social welfare program or another, Democrats are quick to
claim that it is not unaffordable spending that the Republicans dislike, but
poor people. By passing the farm bill this week — after stripping out spending
for the food stamp program — House Republicans showed that that stereotype is
largely true.
Make no
mistake, the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP), formerly known
as food stamps, is out of control, and should be cut. Since 2000, spending on
SNAP increased from just $17 billion per year to more than $78 billion in 2012,
while the number of recipients rose from 17 million in 2000 to more than 48
million today. Nearly one out of every six Americans receives SNAP.
In the
previous iteration of the farm bill, Republicans had attempted to cut SNAP
spending by $20.5 billion over 10 years, paring the program back to 2010 levels
of spending. Democrats opposed those cuts, while some Republicans didn’t
believe the cuts were deep enough. As a result, the farm bill went down to
well-deserved defeat.
In
response the Republican leadership split the bill into two pieces, allowing
Republicans to vote for agricultural subsidies without having to vote for any
funding for food stamps at all. With the Republican leadership whipping the
vote, including threatening wayward committee chairmen, the
welfare-for-farmers-only version passed 216-208, entirely on the strength of
Republican votes. In fact, only 12 Republicans voted against it.
But in
passing the farm bill, Republicans demonstrated that they are just fine with
bloated welfare programs as long as those welfare payments go to well-healed
special interests.
In
2011, the last year for which full data is available, the average farm
household had an income of $87,289, 25 % higher than the average for all
U.S. households. And about a third of the farm subsidies go to the largest four
percent of farm operators. If you want to see real “welfare queens,” look no
further than Pilgrim’s Pride, Tyler Farms, and Riceland Foods.
This
version of the farm bill would cost taxpayers more than $195 billion over the
next 10 years. And while some Republicans have tried to portray this as a cut,
which is only according to the Washington-game of measuring increases relative
to CBO’s projected baseline. In many ways this bill is to the left of proposals
from President Obama. Any Republican who voted for this bill and then claims to
care about the debt or deficits should be laughed off the stage.
It is
true that this farm bill takes some small steps toward reforming some of the
worst aspects of farm policy, notably by reducing (but not eliminating) “direct
payments” to farmers if there is a decline in commodity prices, regardless of
how much they actually planted or how much they would sell their crops for. But
the savings from direct payment cuts are simply shifted to an increase in crop
insurance programs.
Under
this bill, taxpayers would subsidize roughly 62 percent of the premium costs
for farmers who buy insurance to shield themselves against sharp fluctuations
in prices. The insurance effectively enables farmers to lock in high prices no
matter their crop size. The farm bill doesn’t just maintain this program for traditional
beneficiaries such as wheat, soybean, cotton, rice, peanut, and dairy farmers,
it expands the subsidies to include the fishing industry or “seafood
harvesters,” alfalfa grower and the producers of biomass and sweet sorghum. In
addition, the bill includes special peanut revenue insurance, funds to study
extending insurance to cover losses dues to food recalls or health advisories
related to contamination, and protection against business interruption of
poultry producers.
The
bill would also spend $3 billion to cover farmers’ deductibles before their
crop insurance kicks in, in part to offset the end of the direct payments
scheme. As a result, farmers will be almost completely insulated from any
potential losses.
Unsurprisingly,
the bill preserves loan programs and protectionist trade barriers for sugar
growers. While the trade barriers drive up sugar prices by keeping out less
expensive foreign sugar, the Agriculture Department implements a Soviet-style
five-year plan, deciding what total sugar production should be, allotting 54
percent of that production to beet sugar and 46 percent to cane sugar, then
giving each sugar company a specific production quota.
The
House version of the farm bill also maintained a dairy program, similar to the
sugar program. The GAO found that, due to this provision, between 1998 and
2004, U.S. butter prices were more than double international prices and that
U.S. cheese prices were up to 58 percent higher than international prices The
House bill also created a dairy supply management programs that would tax milk
producers who produce “too much” when prices are low. According to the CBO, the
new Dairy Market Stabilization Program could also cost the private sector up to
$100 million annually just to comply with its information and reporting
requirements.
Tree
farmers received their little bit of welfare too. The Tree Assistance Program
(TAP) allows the Secretary of Agriculture to use funds from the Commodity
Credit Corporation to provide assistance to orchardists and nursery growers for
losses of trees due to natural disaster.
And
House Republicans actually made this version of the farm bill even worse than
the one defeated earlier by eliminating the provisions that allowed some the
costliest and most indefensible programs no longer expire after five years.
In the
wake of this bill, Republican claims to stand for free markets or fiscal
responsibility are risible. Their complaints about welfare are merely hypocritical.
No comments:
Post a Comment