In order to maintain a high level of consumption, our parents chose fewer children
by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
by Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
We will, over the
course of the next several days, present seven different reasons for why we
should hate our parents. While the headline may seem unduly provocative we
believe the following arguments will be more than enough to substantiate such a
harsh claim. Some may say our allegation is nothing more than an interesting
intellectual exercise with no valid practical implications. What our parents
did is water under the bridge; dwelling with bygones helps no one!
We beg to differ.
We look at what is happening throughout the world and we see angry, frustrated
young people without jobs, without prospects, without useful academic degrees,
carrying unsustainable debt burdens protesting FOR status quo! One should think
a generation facing so many headwinds of which they are of no responsibility
themselves would demand a revolution and overthrow the power that is.
Perversely, they rather ask for more of the same. They take to the streets and
ask elected and non-elected leaders to continue the policies that brought them
into their predicament in the first place.
We will present
seven reasons for why today’s youth should protest AGAINST status quo by
showing the reader how our parents made a complete mess of what they once
inherited from our grandparents. Hopefully, our little contribution will make a
small, but right step in taking today’s protesters in a new direction.
Reason number one:
in order to maintain a high level of consumption, our parents chose fewer
children
We often hear
about the “baby-boom” problem created by our grandparent’s high fertility rate.
Those children are now retiring, and thus strain the western world’s welfare
system. Before we move on to explore this particular problem, let us just say
that our parents have had a tendency to obfuscate our language and terms,
making rational conversation much harder to achieve.
They somehow
manage to call outright statists for liberal, they call war peacekeeping
operations, and they call fascism right-wing extremism and
so on. The same is true for the term “baby-boom” as if it is something novel
that the new generation is larger the previous one. Our parents blame our
grandparents for the dire straits we are heading into due to the baby-boom
problem. It is not a baby-boom problem; it is a birth-deficit problem! It is
not our grandparents that got a lot of children that causes the problem we now
face; it is the fact that our parents got so few.
They did not want
the extra responsibility of raising a lot of kids. It cost them money and it
took away valuable time which they could rather use to satisfy their own
narcissistic tendencies. This choice of course provided them with the best of
two worlds with few elderly dependencies and simultaneously very few younger
dependencies. Hence they could expand current consumption by imposing a
demographic tax on the future. This is often referred to as a demographic
dividend. Worryingly, for many troubled countries this dividend is now entering
a phase of pay-back!
Let’s explore the demographics
in more detail and see what’s going on in the western (and to some extent the
emerging-) world. One of the best indicators in terms of economic impact from
changing demographics is called dependency ratios. This is the ratio of cohorts
in non-working age relative to cohorts in working age. This ratio gives an
explicit number on how many dependents there are relative to breadwinners.
Contrary to economics in general, demographic trends are relatively certain
since generations already born will by law of nature age and develop in a
highly predictable manner. As the next two chart clearly points out, dependency
ratios will worsen inexorably in the decades that follow. Unfortunately, that
is only half the story, because not all within their working age is actually
working, but are dependents themselves. This is in itself a product of the
welfare state that was built in the post-WWII area, but more on that later. In
many countries participation rates, those within working age that is working or
is looking for work, is depressingly low. Assuming participation rates will be
maintained at their long-term averages, which today are a highly optimistic
assumption, we can also get an idea of the real burden expected to be carried
by our own generation as we move forward.
Now, what if we,
as a generation, retired at an average age of 70 years? Let`s say we start
working on average when we are 23 years and then work until we are 70; an
active, full time working life of 47 years. Further, assume this change in retirement
age is implemented from 2015, with one extra year for every third year until we
reach 70. Even this draconian change will in many countries not be enough to
maintain stable dependency ratios. In Germany for example, the dependency ratio
will still deteriorate to levels far below today despite implementation of
pension reforms that are political impossible. The reader should also observe
the conservative assumptions we have made initially, with people today working
on average from 23 years of age to 65. According to Eurostat, the average age
at which a European worker starts to receive benefits is 58.1 years, with
France at low of 54.5 years. In other words, just to reach the levels we show
in our chart Europe need to increase the retirement age by 7 years and then
start to increase by another 5!
Source: US Census Bureau, own calculations
Source: US Census Bureau, own calculations
Source: US Census Bureau, own calculations
Source: US Census Bureau, own calculations
The change in
developed world demographics is truly staggering and the only argument left we
hear our parents desperately cling to, besides blaming overly fertile
grandparents, is that our generation will be so much richer than they ever
were, so we can afford higher taxes to pay for their retirement. Well, due the
fact that they also taxed away our productivity through consuming previously
invested capital that is not necessarily true. As we explained in the previous blog
post, the accumulation of consumptive debt is detrimental to future growth.
Trend extrapolation may work well in natural science, but not in human science.
It does not follow that economic growth in capitalistic societies the preceding
200 years will mean growth and prosperity the next 200 years. On the contrary,
the period of high growth and increased standard of living is an anomaly both
in time and space. Most people, most of the time does not enjoy the affluence
our parents did.
Conclusion
Our generation
should not expect to retire early and we should expect massive political
pressure to raise our taxes to fund an obvious bankrupt pay-as-you-go system!
No comments:
Post a Comment