Instead of lamenting immigrants we should be welcoming them, especially the low-skilled ones
by David Howden
Early this year, the Saudi Arabian
government decided to crack down on foreign workers. Writing for The Globe and Mail, Martin Dokoupil and
Marwa Rashad argue that this will lead to a “stronger, more
diverse economy.” In particular, they focus on the plethora of businesses open
at the moment — more than they think is necessary — and the resultant reduction
in both “unnecessary” labor and businesses that would be possible if these
foreign workers were forced to leave.
The immigration debate, whether it
occurs in Saudi Arabia, the United States, or even Canada, really boils down to
answering a simple question: Do we want to import workers or goods?
Like money, workers go (when able) to
the place that treats them best. Oftentimes this is where real wages are
highest. Real in this sense means “cost-adjusted,” so that a worker making a
low wage in a low-cost country (say Mexico) may actually have a higher standard
of living than one working at a high-wage job in a high-cost country (perhaps
Switzerland).
There is an enduring tendency for
profits to equalize across all businesses as entrepreneurs move to exploit
opportunities. The same holds true for real wages. As workers move from lower
to higher real-wage areas there is the same equilibrating tendency. The
relative removal of supply from the low-wage country will place upward pressure
on the wages of the remaining workers. The influx of new workers to the
higher-wage country functions in the opposite direction — wages begin to
depress as a result of the increase in relative labor supply.
As long as there is a meaningful
distinction between the standards of living of two countries, we will see the
tendency for labor to move to where it is treated best. We can build walls and
increase immigration requirements, but all this does is make it a little more
costly to make the move. Walls and regulations do nothing to remove the
disparity in living standards which is the original incentive driving
immigrants to relocate in search of a better life.
Fresh immigrants are at an obvious
disadvantage compared to natives. They may not speak the language. Or they lack
a network of contacts for jobs or social support. Their one “advantage” is an
ability and willingness to work for lower wages than their more established
native-born counterparts. Part of this willingness to work for lower wages is
because their skill set is less developed (lack of language skills in particular
can be a big factor). Another factor is that even a low wage in their new
country compares well to the wage they were receiving back “home.” Perhaps they
are willing to accept lower wages in exchange for the future possibilities open
to their children: education, employment, or otherwise.
What motivates the immigrants is largely
beside the point. All we need to realize is that these workers want to come
here, and that at some wage they are competitive.
What are the benefits a country reaps
from immigrants flowing in? Cheaper wages are an obvious answer, though that is
also largely beside the point. The real benefits are the increased
opportunities that domestic citizens get. With less-skilled jobs being
performed by these new workers, domestic citizens can set their sights on the
more lucrative opportunities made possible by less-expensive goods and
services, and a more diverse labor pool available to entrepreneurs and their
employees.
In economics we say that the cost of
something is the foregone opportunity. The activity that an action prohibited
is the real cost of a choice. To employ me at a low-skilled job, my employer
would need to pay me a compensating high wage. My opportunities say so! If I
was not to be employed in a low-skilled job I would remain at my own present
job as a university professor. This is an extreme example, though the basic
rationale rings true for all workers.
Hiring less expensive foreign-born
workers makes sense as the opportunity cost is generally lower. Now consider a
ban on immigration.
There are jobs in any country which will
only be taken if the price is right. Employing a worker at the right wage is a
difficult task, though one that is aided by the increased labor pool immigrants
provide. We often lament that our own citizens don’t want to do some jobs
because “they are too good for them.” What we really mean that for the going
wage our opportunities are better, and it is unattractive for our domestic-born
workers to perform these tasks. Sometimes it is because we don’t want to take a
lower-wage job and risk missing a better opportunity that arises (recent
unemployed graduates living at home with mom and dad while low-skilled and
low-wage jobs go unfilled is a good case in point). Other times it is because
some jobs are such low value-added that employers cannot raise wage rates to
attract domestic workers (jobs in cost centers, like janitorial positions, often fit
this bill).
If we ban immigrants from entering the
country we are really banning these jobs from being performed. We will also
have to import the fruits of these jobs if we don’t import the lower-cost labor
to perform them. There is evidence in the U.S. that strengthening American
immigration laws has resulted in the exportation of agricultural jobs to
Mexico. If the workers cannot come here we will send the work to them.
Instead of lamenting immigrants we
should be welcoming them, especially the low-skilled ones. The alternative to having them here is much worse.
No comments:
Post a Comment