It is impossible for the
U.S. to maintain the reserve currency and run trade surpluses
By CHARLES HUGH SMITH
By CHARLES HUGH SMITH
Many well-meaning commentators look back on the era of strong
private-sector unions and robust U.S. trade surpluses with longing. The
Progressive consensus (articulated by Robert Reich, among others) is that
unions gave the working and middle classes bargaining power that has been lost
in the decline of unions.
Other commentators look back with similar nostalgia on the large trade
surpluses (i.e. current account surplus) of the same era--the 1950s and 1960s.
The two trends are connected. Unions had bargaining
power because the corporations on the other side of the table were generally
cartels (autos, steel, etc.) that were largely domestic, meaning that they were
captive to domestic markets and politics.
All these conditions have changed. Present-day
U.S. corporations are global, not domestic; up to 75% of their sales and/or
profits are generated in overseas markets, and a similar percentage of their
workforces are also overseas, not just for cost reasons but to stay close to
the markets generating their profits.
Free-trade agreements restrict attempts to protect domestic markets from
overseas competition, and as a result domestic unions have essentially zero
bargaining power with either nominally American firms or their global
competitors in most markets. The only sectors open to union bargaining power
are domestic monopolies or cartels with no overseas competition, i.e. the
government, which is why the union movement is now dominated by public unions.
The trade surpluses vanished for two reasons: global competition and protection of the dollar as the world's reserve currency. This is a
difficult issue to grasp, so let's do it in parts:
1. When the global exporting nations recovered after World War II, their costs of labor and production were cheaper than American industry, which was hobbled by the strong dollar. For example, $1 bought 250 yen as recently as the early 1970s. Today, it barely buys 100 yen.
2. As a result, cheap imports took market share from domestic producers (believe it or not, BMWs were once relatively cheap), and the U.S. trade balance went negative, i.e. the U.S. ran trade deficits. To settle the deficits, the U.S. had to ship gold to the creditor nations.
3. As the trade deficits expanded, America's gold holdings shrank. The writing was on the wall: continued deficits would eventually shrink the U.S. gold holdings to zero, at which point deficits would be impossible to sustain.
4. As a result, President Nixon closed the gold window and the U.S. dollar floated in a market of supply and demand.
What
Will Benefit from Global Recession? The U.S. Dollar (October 9,
2012)
Understanding
the "Exorbitant Privilege" of the U.S. Dollar (November
19, 2012)
Prior to 1971, the dollar was backed by gold, which acted as a supra-national
anchor to the dollar's reserve status. The gold standard inhibited both massive
trade deficits and money creation, so it was jettisoned.
The Triffin paradox is a theory that when a
national currency also serves as an international reserve currency, there could
be conflicts of interest between short-term domestic and long-term
international economic objectives. This dilemma was first identified by
Belgian-American economist Robert Triffin in the 1960s, who pointed out that
the country whose currency foreign nations wish to hold (the global reserve
currency) must be willing to supply the world with an extra supply of
its currency to fulfill world demand for this 'reserve' currency (foreign
exchange reserves) and thus cause a trade deficit. (emphasis added)
The use of a national currency (i.e. the U.S.
dollar) as global reserve currency leads to a tension between national monetary
policy and global monetary policy. This is reflected in fundamental imbalances
in the balance of payments, specifically the current account: some goals
require an overall flow of dollars out of the United States, while others
require an overall flow of dollars in to the United States. Net currency
inflows and outflows cannot both happen at once.
In other words, the U.S. must "export" U.S. dollars by running a
trade deficit to supply the world with dollars to hold as reserves and to use
to pay debt denominated in dollars. Other
nations need U.S. dollars in reserve to back their own credit creation.
It is impossible for the U.S. to maintain the reserve currency and run trade surpluses. It's
Hobson's Choice: if you run trade surpluses, you cannot supply the global
economy with the currency flows it needs for trade, reserves, payment of debt
denominated in the reserve currency and credit expansion.
If you don't possess the reserve currency, you can't print money and have
it accepted as payment. (The euro and yen are quasi-reserve currencies based on
the size of the European Union and Japanese economies, but neither acts as the primary
reserve and as a result both are vulnerable to currency crises, despite the
conventional wisdom that both are on the same footing as the U.S. dollar.)
Unions have little bargaining power in a global economy with surplus labor
and mobile capital, and trade surpluses are impossible for the nation
possessing the reserve currency. Some view this as a liability, but any
currency that is not the reserve currency is vulnerable to a currency/credit
crisis and collapse, for currency and credit are tied at the hip through
reserves.
Those who disbelieve that the yuan, yen and euro are vulnerable to currency/credit crises--please check in around September 2015.
Those who disbelieve that the yuan, yen and euro are vulnerable to currency/credit crises--please check in around September 2015.
No comments:
Post a Comment